This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

\draftSpacing

1.5

\shortTitle

Rise of the Kniesians \pubMonthMonth \pubYearYear \pubVolumeVol \pubIssueIssue \JELA14, B20, B31 \Keywordssocial network; professor-student relationship; Nobel Prize

Rise of the Kniesians: The professor-student network of Nobel laureates in economics

Richard S.J. Tol Tol: Department of Economics, University of Sussex, BN1 9SL Falmer, United Kingdom, [email protected]; Institute for Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, The Netherlands; Department of Spatial Economics, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, The Netherlands; Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam, The Netherlands; CESifo, Munich, Germany; Payne Institute of Earth Resources, Colorado School of Mines, Golden, CO, USA. Richard Blundell, Ernst Fehr, Benjamin Friedman, Jerry Hausman, David Hendry, Edward Lazear, Richard Levin, John Moore, Gerhard Orosel and Larry Summers kindly answered questions about their ancestry. Two anonymous referees, Irwin Collier, Peter Dolton and Stephen Zeff had helpful information and comments.
Abstract

The paper presents the professor-student network of Nobel laureates in economics. 82 of the 87 Nobelists belong to one family tree. The remaining 5 belong to 3 separate trees. There are 376 men in the graph, and 5 women. Karl Knies is the central-most professor, followed by Wassily Leontief. No classical and few neo-classical economists have left notable descendants. Harvard is the central-most university, followed by Chicago and Berlin. Most candidates for the Nobel prize belong to the main family tree, but new trees may arise for the students of Terence Gorman and Denis Sargan.

”It is Knies, however, whom I am glad to acknowledge, more than any other one man, as My Master.” (Ely, 1938)

1 Introduction

The highest accolade in economics, the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel and its winners attract extraordinary attention, including how different Laureates relate to each other. Besides the gossip, particular attention has been paid to schools of thought and influential institutions (McCarty, 2000; Vane and Mulhearn, 2005; Breit and Hirsch, 2009; Boettke, Fink and Smith, 2012; Chan and Torgler, 2012; Claes and de Ceuster, 2013; Spencer and Macpherson, 2015; Solow and Murray, 2015; Offer and Söderberg, 2016). Although anecdotes of who studied with whom are widely known, no one has comprehensively mapped the professor-student relationships of all Nobel Laureates in economics. This paper does just that.

I show that most Nobelists are related, often closely.111Zuckerman (1996) and Chan and Torgler (2015) show that Nobelists in other disciplines cluster too. The 2017 Laureate, Richard H. Thaler, is typically described as an outsider in the press (Appelbaum, 2017; Avent, 2017; Harford, 2017; Partington, 2017; Vitasek, 2017)—but that may be a mischaracterisation of someone with a PhD from the University of Rochester, Gary S. Becker and Robert E. Lucas as academic uncles, and James J. Heckman as an academic cousin. William J. Baumol and his student Lionel W. McKenzie were not honored by a trip to Stockholm, inexplicably so according to some (Minniti, 2016; Weintraub, 2011). Actually, Baumol is the academic brother of John R. Hicks, and uncle to Franco Modigliani, Amartya Sen and Joseph E. Stiglitz. Paul M. Romer is McKenzie’s grandstudent. Some argue that Margaret G. Reid should have shared the Nobel Prize with Gary S. Becker (Yi, 1996). Whatever the merits of this argument, a lack of connections was not part of it: Reid is Ronald Coase’ first cousin once removed, she had a PhD from the University of Chicago, and taught there for many years. A comprehensive map of all Laureates, including a way to connect those that could or should have won, is useful to dispel myths and ugly rumours.

You can interpret the close relationships between Nobelists as a manifestation of the clustering of quality: The best professors congregate in the best schools (Ellison, 2013), reinforce each other (Azoulay, Zivin and Wang, 2010; Borjas and Doran, 2012; Bosquet and Combes, 2017; Oyer, 2006), and select the best students (Athey et al., 2007). You can also see this as a manifestation of the feudal nature of academia and the nepotism implied (Combes, Linnemer and Visser, 2008; Hamermesh and Schmidt, 2003; Laband and Piette, 1994; Medoff, 2003). Zuckerman (1996) points out that Nobelists have the right to nominate, and put their proteges forward. She argues, though, that matching on quality, training, and competition between the students of Nobel Laureates are more important in explaining the success of Nobel students.

Tracing the Nobel network over time illustrates key features of the development of economics as a discipline. The Scandinavian branches of the network were ascendant for a while, but key people stayed put in or returned to Norway and Sweden and lost global influence, unlike the Dutch who moved to the USA and kept winning. The French branch moved to the USA too, and withered. The current network is dominated by the UK and the USA, with competition between East Coast and Great Lakes, and deep roots in Austria, Germany and France uniting many. Intriguingly, none of the great classical economists—Smith, Say, Ricardo, Malthus, Mill, Marx—and pre-classical economists—Ibn Khaldun, Petty, Quesnay, Cantillon, Turgot, Galiani—is connected to the Nobelists, and only one of the neo-classical revolutionaries: Carl Menger—Marshall, Walras, Jevons, Pareto and Pigou made enduring contributions to economic thought, but only through their writings, not through their students.222John Maynard Keynes was taught and mentored by Marshall and Pigou, but was supervised by W.E. Johnson and A.N. Whitehead. In those days, apparently, economics was not yet a discipline that could be taught to young scholars, or at least the leaders of the profession did not see it this way.

This is specific to economics: Scholars in the humanities and natural sciences can trace their ancestry to great names of times past, and indeed many economists descend from famous non-economists—including people whose work we use, such as the Bernouillis, Gauss, Lagrange, Lyapunov and Pearson, and people whose work is less obviously relevant, such as Bohr, Erasmus, Heisenberg, Luther and Maxwell. In other words, economics was taken over by people from other disciplines, much like economists now work on subjects that traditionally were the exclusive domain of political scientists, anthropologists, psychologists and biologists.

Representing the network as a graph and adding degree-granting institutions, I identify central professors and schools. The results may be surprising. A relatively obscure member of the German Historical School, Karl Knies emerges as the central-most thesis advisor. Knies is not nearly as famous as his students Eugen Böhm von Bawerk (Von Mises, 2016), John Bates Clark (Homan, 1927; Leonard, 2003), and Richard T. Ely (Rader, 1966; Thies and Pecquet, 2010). Berlin, Göttingen and Vienna are the top 10 of central-most schools, with more obvious candidates such as Harvard and Chicago.

I also consider the likely candidates for future Nobel Prizes, revealing that the current network is likely to produce future winners. New networks may emerge as well, particularly around the students, grandstudents and great-grandstudents of Terence Gorman.

The paper proceeds as follows. Data and methods are presented in the next section. Section 3 discusses the results. Section 4 concludes.

2 Data and methods

2.1 Data

The list of Nobel laureates was taken from IDEAS/RePEc. The list of Nobel candidates is Clarivate’s 2020 list of Citation Laureates. Speculation is rife in the run-up to the Nobel Prize announcement and lists of candidates abound. The Clarivate list is based on objective criteria—citation numbers in economics journals—and has a reasonable prediction record. It largely overlaps with other lists.

Data on ancestry and final degree were gathered from and stored on AcademicTree.org, a collaborative tool for building an academic genealogy for all disciplines (David and Hayden, 2012). The economics tree333I follow the data source and use the colloquial expression ”tree” in this paper. Strictly, this is a directed acyclic graph or polytree. contains over 21,000 economists, the overall tree almost 700,000 academics. Where AcademicTree was incomplete, I added data from the Mathematics Genealogy Project, which actually includes many economists, and from RePEc Genealogy, which focuses on economists but is limited in its historical depth. If all three sources fell short, I used Wikipedia, studied CVs, obituaries and acknowledgements in early papers, and dug up the occasional thesis. When all that failed, I contacted people or their students directly. The results can be found on AcademicTree.org. The data can be amended where needed and extended to include the reader’s favorite economists.

The data are not perfect. Formal professor-student relationships are recorded, but may be less important than informal mentoring.444Friedrich von Wieser is one example. He co-advised Friedrich von Hayek with Carl Menger and Ludwig von Mises, but as Menger was both Mises’ and Wieser’s advisor, Menger takes most of the numerical credit for Hayek’s success. Wieser influenced Mises and Joseph Schumpeter, but his brother-in-law Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk was their official advisor. The influence metric presented below does not do justice to Wieser’s contribution. Some professors are more important than others.555I had three PhD advisers. One taught me statistics, one taught me office politics, and one taught me nothing before I finished my PhD but much after. I learned economics from people who were not on my committee. The formalization of research training is a recent development, and different countries made this transition at different times. In the generation of professors now retiring in the UK and the Netherlands, it was not uncommon to not have a PhD. Germany and Austria have the Habilitation, a degree after the PhD. France used to have that too. An Italian doctorate is often seen as the degree to enter a PhD in England or the USA. These norms have changed over the centuries that are spanned by the data. The edges in the graph are not uniform. Some data are missing, and some people were self-taught—no distinction is made. For earlier generations, historians have focused on prominent scholars, their professors and their students. Some universities have excellent online records, other universities closely guard graduation data.

The professors in the tree presented here are, in most cases, the formal PhD advisors to the students in the tree; often two per student, but one advisor or three are not uncommon. Where appropriate, the advisor of the Habilitation or Master’s thesis is either added to or used instead of the PhD advisor. In a few cases, an informal mentor is used.

The data are taken at face value. No probabilities are assigned, or fuzzy memberships. A limited sensitivity analysis is shown below. Data and algorithms are in the public domain for anyone to add, alter or perform their preferred sensitivity analysis.

2.2 Methods

Data were transferred to Matlab for visualization and analysis. Five generations were included, unless graphs could be connected by including more distant ancestors, in which case the closest common ancestor was included. Without these two restrictions, the network would be dominated by the intricate relationships of non-economists of times long past and the somewhat speculative lineage of Jesus Christ. Data are interpreted as a directed acyclic graph—because in most cases students learn more from their professors than the other way around—with unweighted edges—because we do not know, in most cases, which advisor was more influential. I use a minor modification of an outcloseness measure cA(i)c^{A}(i) for network centrality:

(1) cA(i)=(AiN1)21jCi,jc^{A}(i)=\left(\frac{A_{i}}{N-1}\right)^{2}\frac{1}{\sum_{j}C_{i,j}}

where AiA_{i} is the number of Nobel nodes that can be reached from node ii, NN is the number of nodes, and Ci,jC_{i,j} is the distance from node ii to any Nobel node. If the word Nobel is dropped, this reverts to the measure of outcloseness as defined by Bavelas (1950) for a connected graph and extended, in a seemingly ad hoc but not unreasonable way, by Matlab to unconnected graphs by multiplication with the square of the fraction of nodes reachable.

In a connected graph, Equation (1) is the arithmetic mean of the distance to all other nodes. Marchiori and Latora (2000) propose the harmonic mean as a measure of distance:666Earlier, Gil-Mendieta and Schmidt (1996) suggested its inverse as a measure of closeness.

(2) cH(i)=(N1)j1Ci,jc^{H}(i)=(N-1)\sum_{j}\frac{1}{C_{i,j}}

The key advantage of the harmonic mean is that it applies to connected as well as unconnected graphs—for unreachable nodes Ci,j=C_{i,j}=\infty. In Equation (2), the number of unreachable nodes is penalized linearly; in Equation (1), the penalty is quadratic. In this context, when distance is restricted to distance to a Nobel laureate, the harmonic mean has the additional advantage that proximity is emphasized at the expense of distal relationships. I therefore use the harmonic mean distance as my key measure of centrality, and the arithmetic mean as a robustness check.

Note that outcloseness on a polytree measures ancestry. Two students of the same professor are not close. The professor is close to both of them, but they are not close to each other.777An undirected graph would show that academic siblings are close. However, as professors frequently co-advise new students with their former students, an undirected graph would have cycles.

For Nobel candidates, what matters is their distance to the graph, rather than the graph’s distance to them. This is an incloseness measure, rather than an outcloseness one. It is readily computed by replacing Ci,jC_{i,j} by Cj,iC_{j,i} in Equation (2).

I measure the change in the network over time by the Graph Edit Distance (Sanfeliu and Fu, 1983). The edit distance between graph AA and BB equals the number of nodes and edges that need to be added to (or removed from) AA to make AA isomorphic to BB. Typically, computing the Graph Edit Distance is a n-p hard problem, but in this case the graph for the previous year is a subgraph of the graph for the current year. Indeed, the algorithm that builds the graph for year tt uses the graph for year t1t-1 as its starting point. This also means that the edits make the graphs identical, rather than just isomorphic.

Besides the changes in the overall graph over time, I am also interested in changes in the centrality of individuals. While the centrality measures defined above have a cardinal interpretation at any point in time, this is not true for changes in centrality.888This is easily seen. Consider a graph. Add a node with a single edge to the central-most node. Add NN unconnected nodes. If NN is sufficiently large, centrality falls numerically, even though the central-most node has become more central. I therefore use changes in the centrality rank to assess changes over time.

3 Nobelists

Ragnar Frisch, Jan Tinbergen999Jan’s biological brother, Niko, won the Nobel Prize for Physiology in 1973. and Paul A. Samuelson all start their own graphs. That is, they do not share an ancestor. Simon S. Kuznets and Samuelson do share an ancestor in Christian Gottlob Heyne, an 18th century classicist and archaeologist at the University of Göttingen, Germany. Kenneth J. Arrow starts his own graph.101010Arrow’s biological sister was married to Samuelson’s biological brother. John R. Hicks was a grandstudent of Carl Menger, who was also a great-grandprofessor of Samuelson. Wassily Leontief was advisor of Samuelson, who is thus the first second-generation Nobelist. Leontief was the first to win the Nobel Prize after his student. F.A. Hayek, Hicks’ adviser, was the second. Gunnar Myrdal111111Myrdal’s wife, Alva Reimer, won the Nobel Peace Prize in 1982. is a distant descendant of Pierre Varignon, an 18th century mathematician at the Royal Academy in Paris, France; Arrow also descends from Varignon. After five years, there are nine Nobel laureates, five of whom are part of a single family tree; there is one tree with two Nobelists (Arrow, Myrdal); and two with one (Frisch, Tinbergen).

Leonid Kantorovich and Leontief are distant descendents of Johann Friedrich Pfaff, a 19th century mathematician at the University of Halle-Wittenberg, Germany. Tjalling C. Koopmans was a student of Tinbergen and Hendrik Kramer, who descends from Heyne. Koopmans thus connects the Tinbergen graph to the main one. Milton Friedman was a student of Kuznets, and shares an ancestor with Samuelson in Karl Knies, a 19th century economist at the University of Heidelberg, Germany.

James E. Meade starts his own graph. Like Myrdal (and Eli Heckscher), Bertil Ohlin was a student of Karl Gustav Cassel. This completes the Swedish branch of the graph—in contrast with the Dutch branch, which continues to grow, as key people moved to the USA.

Herbert A. Simon was a student of Henry Schultz, like Friedman was. Theodore W. Schultz was a great-grandstudent of Knies. W. Arthur Lewis and Hicks are both grandstudents of Edwin Cannan. Lawrence R. Klein was Samuelson’s student. James Tobin was Joseph Schumpeter’s student, like Samuelson, and a grandstudent of Werner Sombart, who with Ladislaus Bortkiewicz advised Leontief.121212A referee points out that Sombart called on Bortkiewicz to check Leontief’s mathematics. George J. Stigler was a great-grandstudent of both Clark and Ely. In 1982, 14 years after the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences was first awarded, there is a well-established family tree.

Gerard Debreu starts his own graph. Like Meade, Richard Stone was a student of John Maynard Keynes. He was also a great-grandstudent of Ely and so related to Schultz and Stigler. Stone thus connects the UK and the US graphs. Stone also brings the first female to the graph: Beatrice Potter Webb,131313Beatrice Potter and Beatrix Potter are different people. who co-founded the London School of Economics.

Franco Modigliani is a grandstudent of Lionel Robbins, one of Hicks’ advisers, and a great-grandstudent of Bawerk. Like Stigler, James M. Buchanan was a student of Frank H. Knight. Like Samuelson, Robert M. Solow was a student of Leontief.

Debreu was a post-doc with Maurice F.C. Allais. This completes the French graph. Trygve M. Haavelmo was a student of Frisch. This completes the Norwegian graph.

William F. Sharpe was a great-grandstudent of Harold Hotelling, who was Arrow’s adviser. Merton M. Miller was a grandstudent of Ludwig von Mises, Hayek’s advisor. Harry M. Markowitz was Jacob Marschak’s student, like Modigliani. Markowitz was also a student of Friedman, who was Kuznets’ student. Markowitz is thus the first third-generation Nobelist.

Like Stigler and Buchanan, Ronald H. Coase was a student of Knight. Gary S. Becker was a grandstudent of Schultz, the adviser of Friedman and Simon. Robert W. Fogel was Kuznets’ student. Douglas C. North was advised by Melvin M. Knight,141414Melvin was a biological brother of Frank. who was a grandstudent of Henry Moore, like Friedman and Simon.

John C. Harsanyi was a student of Arrow. John F. Nash and Reinhard J.R. Selten are distant descendants of Carl Gauss, and so is Leontief. Selten also descends from Simeon-Denis Poisson as does Hotelling. Selten thus connects the Arrow-Sharpe-Harsanyi/Myrdal-Ohlin graph with the main one.

Robert E. Lucas was a student of Gregg Lewis, like Becker. Lucas is also a great-great-grandstudent of Ely, and so related to many other Nobelists. James E. Mirrlees was a student of Stone. William S. Vickrey was a grandstudent of Edwin Seligman, like Frank Knight. Robert C. Merton was a student of Samuelson. Myron S. Scholes was Miller’s student. Eugene F. Fama was Scholes’ other adviser. Sixteen years after receiving his prize, Scholes would become the first Nobelist with two Nobel advisers.

Amartya Sen was a grandstudent of Robbins, like Modigliani. Joan Robinson was an adviser. She is the second woman in the graph. Robert A. Mundell was a great-grandstudent of James Laughlin, Kuznets’ grandprofessor, and of Allyn Abbot Young, Knight’s professor. Daniel L. McFadden was a grandstudent of Koopmans and Jakob Marschak, who advised Modigliani. James J. Heckman was a grandstudent of Lewis and Tobin, and a great-grandstudent of Klein. George A. Akerlof was a student of Solow, A. Michael Spence a grandstudent of Leontief. Joseph E. Stiglitz was a student of Robinson, a grandstudent of Robbins and a great-grandstudent of Young. Year after year, the Nobel Prize is awarded to close relatives of previous winners.

Vernon L. Smith was a student of Leontief. Daniel Kahneman’s great-great-great-great-grandprofessor was John Dewey, who was grandprofessor of Kuznets. One of Kahneman’s advisers was Susan Ervin-Tripp, the third woman in the graph. Robert F. Engle was a great-great-grandstudent of Wesley Clair Mitchell, Kuznets’ professor. Clive W.J. Granger was a great-great-great-grandstudent of Eliakim Moore, Hotelling’s grandprofessor. Finn E. Kydland was a student of Edward C. Prescott, a grandstudent of Leontief. They are the first student-professor pair to jointly win. Robert J. Aumann was great-grandstudent of Solomon Lefschetz, who was Nash’ grandprofessor. Thomas C. Schelling was Leontief’s student, and a grandstudent of Schumpeter, who advised Samuelson and Tobin. Edmund S. Phelps was Tobin’s student. Eric S. Maskin and Roger B. Myerson are Arrow’s students. Leonid Hurwicz was Koopmans’ student and a post-doc with Samuelson. Hurwicz is thus a double third-generation Nobelist. McFadden is a fourth-generation Nobelist, and a double one at that.

Paul Krugman was a grandstudent of Mundell. Oliver Williamson was Simon’s student and Stigler’s grandstudent. Elinor Ostrom is the first female Nobelist, and only the fourth woman in the graph. Her grandprofessor was Robert K. Merton151515Robert K. was the biological father of Robert C., a descendant of Friedrich Trendelenburg, Dewey’s grandprofessor. Like Kahneman before her, Ostrom is part of the main family of Nobelists.

Peter A. Diamond was Solow’s student, and Dale T. Mortensen Leontief’s grandstudent. Christopher A. Pissarides has his own graph.

Thomas J. Sargent was a great-grandstudent of Arthur Smithies, Schumpeter’s student and Schelling’s adviser. Christopher A. Sims was Harold S. Houthakker’s student, who was Pieter de Wolff’s student, who was Tinbergen’s student.161616De Wolff is my great-grandprofessor. Lloyd S. Shapley was Alfred Tucker’s student, like Nash. Alvin E. Roth descends from Gauss and Poisson. Lars Peter Hansen is Sims’ student, Robert J. Shiller Modigliani’s. Eugene F. Fama is Miller’s student and Scholes’ professor. Jean Tirole is Maskin’s student, Angus Deaton Stone’s. Bengt Holmström is Robert Wilson’s student, like Roth. Oliver Hart is a grandstudent of Solow and Diamond. Like Heckman, Richard H. Thaler is a grandstudent of Lewis, Becker’s and Lucas’ adviser.

William D. Nordhaus is the third of Solow’s students to win the Nobel prize. Paul Romer studied with a Nobel laureate too (Lucas). His other advisor was José Scheinkman, who is connected with the rest of the tree via Lionel McKenzie, William Baumol and Oskar Morgenstern.

Esther Duflo shared the Nobel Prize with two of her advisers, Abhijit Banerjee and Michael Kremer. Her third adviser was Joshua Angrist, the 2021 winner, who’s adviser was David Card, who also won in 2021. Card is a great-great-grandstudent of Modigliani. Banerjee is a student of Maskin. This makes Duflo a fourth-generation Nobelist. Kremer is a great-grandstudent of Schultz, via Zvi Griliches and Robert Barro.

Paul Milgrom shared the Nobel prize with his advisor, Robert B. Wilson. Milgrom is the third of Wilson’s students to win the Nobel prize, after Holmström and Roth.

The 2021 Nobelists Angrist and Card were added to the tree in 2019. They are the fourth professor-student pair to win the Nobel prize. The third 2021 Nobelist, Guido Imbens, is a grandstudent of Frank Hahn and so descends from Ely, and a great-great-grandstudent of Keynes.

There are 376 men in the graph, and 5 women. There are 85 male Nobelists, 2 female.

3.1 The Nobel network over time

Figure 1 shows the complete network for 2021; there is also a video of all networks since 1969. The tree starts with Alexander Hamilton (of musical fame), Christian Heyne (a philosopher) and Christian Hausen (a mathematician). Modigliani and Leontief are the Nobelists with the largest number of descendant generations. The Nobelists who have yet to produce Nobel offspring are at the bottom of the graph.

Figure 2 quantifies the changes over time. We start with two disjoint graphs. At five occasions, a new, disjoint graph is added. At three occasions, previously disjoint graphs are joined. At the end, there are four disjoint graphs: Frisch-Haavelmo; Allais-Debreu; Pissarides; and all other Nobelists. The final network is messy, as professors group and regroup to advise different students, and professors team up with their students and grandstudents to teach a new generation—but the key point is that Nobelists are connected.

Refer to caption
Figure 1: The complete professor-student network of Nobel Prize laureates in economics.
{figurenotes}

Nobelists are marked in magenta.

Figure 2 shows that the graph edit distance—the number of new nodes and edges—is often small. In 28 out of 53 years, the distance is 10 or less. This is a different way of revealing the same information: New Nobelists are closely related to previous Nobelists. The largest change in the network was in 1975, when 96 edits were needed to include Kantorovich and Koopmans and connect them to the main graph. 66 edits where needed to connect Kuznets to Samuelson in 1971. 56 edits were needed in 1994 for (Harsanyi,) Nash and Selten. Kahneman (and Smith) in 2002 needed 48 edits, and Ostrom (and Williamson) 40 edits in 2009. These results may strike us as odd, but the current reader sees the earlier Nobel laureates as the ultimate insiders. They were not at the time.

Furthermore, as shown above, Kahneman and Ostrom are not as alien to the economics profession as sometimes claimed. Both studied core issues in economics—rationality and public goods, respectively—but from a different perspective—psychology and political science, respectively. But they share their academic lineage with many of the great economists.

Refer to caption
Figure 2: Graph edit distance and change in the number of disjoint graphs.

TOT HIER

Table 1 shows the central-most professors in the network, over time.171717See Waumans and Bersini (2016) for the evolution over time of the citation centrality of academic papers. On both distance measures—harmonic, see Equation (2), and arithmetic, see Equation (1)—Karl Knies is the most central person at the moment. Using the arithmetic mean distance, which emphasizes connectivity over proximity, he has been since 1981. Using the harmonic mean distance, which emphasizes proximity over connectivity, Knies and Leontief have frequently swapped rank, with Robert Shiller pushing Knies into the lead in 2013, a position weakened by Oliver Hart in 2016 but strengthened by Richard Thaler in 2017. Others, including Henry Schultz and Josef Schumpeter, were particularly central in earlier years.

Table 1: Central-most professors over time.
arithmetic harmonic
Knies 1: 1981-2021 1: 2019-2021, 2013-2017, 2007-2009, 1982-2004
2: - 2: 2018, 2016, 2010-2012, 2005-2005, 1981
3: - 3: 1980
Leontief 1: 1970-1972 1: 2018, 2010-2012, 2005-2006, 1970-1972
2: - 2: 2019-2021, 2017, 2015, 2007-2009, 2004
3: 2004-2021, 1973 3: 2002-2003, 1973
Schultz 1: 1978-1980 1: 1978-1979
3: - 3: 1995, 1980
Bawerk 3: 1990-1992, 1985-1986, 1981 3: 1990-1992, 1985-1986
Sombart 1: 1973 1: -
2: - 2: 1981
3: 1987-1989, 1974-1976 3: 1987-1989
Schumpeter 1: 1970-1972 1: 1981, 1970-1972
2: 1981-1983 2: 1982-1983
3: 1984, 1973 3: 1984-1986, 1973
Mises 1: 1980, 1974-1976, 1972 1: 1972-1980
2: 1977 2: 1981
3: 1978-1979, 1973 3: -
Menger 2: 1974-1976 2: 1980, 1974-1976
3: 1977 3: 1977
Cassel 1: 1977-1980 1: 1977-1979
3: - 3: 1980
{tablenotes}

Shown are the ranks of the most central professors of economics, as measured by their (arithmetic or harmonic) average distance to Nobelists. Leaders in the period 1969-1978 are omitted. Knies’ professor, Bruno Hildebrand, and grandprofessor, Maximilian Duncker, are also left out.

Table 2 shows the current top 10. The key people are Knies and Leontief. Their professors and grandprofessors are included because they too are academic ancestors of Nobel Laureates, even though they did not contribute (much) to the discipline. Schumpeter is included as the professor of Samuelson and Tobin and the grandprofessor of Schelling. Heyne connects three branches of the main graph.

Table 2: Central-most professors in 2021.
arithmetic harmonic
1 Knies Knies
2 Hildebrand Leontief
3 Leontief Hildebrand
4 Duncker Sombart
5 Sombart Duncker
6 Bawerk Bawerk
7 Papencordt Bortkiewicz
8 Heyne Papencordt
9 Bortkiewicz Heyne
10 Schlegel Schultz
{tablenotes}

Shown are the ten most central professors of economics, as measured by their (arithmetic or harmonic) average distance to Nobelists.

Figures 3 and 4 shows selected subgraphs, for Kuznets (4 Nobelists), Keynes (5 Nobelists), Tinbergen (6 Nobelists) and Hotelling (8 Nobelists). These graphs are simple. The Hotelling graph shows the branching that make it hard to display made nodes. The Keynes graph shows that Stone was his student, grandstudent, and great-grandstudent. Figure 5 shows the subgraphs for Knies (42 Nobelists, all distant) and Leontief (16 Nobelists, most close). The Leontief shows the key role he and his (students’) students played in economics. The 1973 and 2000 Nobel prizes span six generations. The Knies graph again shows the complex relationships between Nobelists. The tree first splits between Bawerk, Clark and Ely and later rejoins.

Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 3: Selected subgraphs: Kuznets and Keynes.
Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 4: Selected subgraphs: Tinberger and Hotelling.
Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 5: Selected subgraphs: Leontief and Knies.

3.2 Sensitivity analysis

Figure 1 is based on the nearest common ancestor of a new Laureate and any of the previous ones. This algorithm does not necessarily lead to the same, minimum spanning graph if all Nobel Prizes were awarded in 2021. In order to test whether this affects centrality, I include all ancestors of all Laureates, appropriately cut-off at William of Ockham.181818The interested reader can trace Ockham’s lineage to John the Baptist. The expanded graph is quite a bit larger, with 1103 instead of 381 nodes. Centrality does not change much, however. The main difference is that Jakob Thomasius enters the top 10 of most central ancestors. Thomasius was a 17th century philosopher at the University of Leipzig, and a common ancestor of common ancestors. The expanded graph contains many famous philosophers, theologists, jurists, physicists, biologists, and chemists—but no classical or pre-classical economists.

Some entries on AcademicTree.org are disputed and historical facts continue to be discovered. I focus on four individuals. Carl Menger supervised the Habilitation of Eugen Böhm von Bawerk, and arranged for his studies with Knies and Hildebrand. This edge was added. Leonid Hurwicz fled Poland after obtaining his PhD from an unknown adviser in 1938. While von Hayek and von Mises provided shelter, they did not contribute to his education. Similarly, John Hicks joined Hayek and Robbins after finishing his education. These edges were removed. This would create a separate Hurwicz-McFadden tree. However, McFadden edited his AcademicTree entry to include Arrow, Uzawa (a student of Arrow) and Chipman (a student of Machlup). These edges were added. In his autobiography, Gary Becker stresses the importance of Director, Friedman, Savage and Schultz to his intellectual development. Alfred Marshall mentored John Maynard Keynes. These edges were added.191919I am grateful to an anonymous referee for three of the six adjustments, two other referees for two others.

These changes in the network lead to changes in the centrality of the people in the network. Koopmans and other people in the Tinbergen tree become less central. Friedman and Menger become more central. Karl Knies remains the central-most figure in the network.

3.3 Universities

Figure 6 shows the key places of learning, ranked by their centrality in 2020. A video shows location and centrality over time. I show total centrality: A university is granted one point if a Nobel Laureate obtained his PhD there. The university where his professor graduated is awarded half a point, with further ancestors’ universities granted points in proportion to the arithmetic centrality measure (1). Figure 6 shows market share, as levels increase with time. In total, 61 universities are included but Figure 6 only shows the top 10. Harvard comes out top, closely followed by Chicago and MIT. Berlin, Göttingen and Vienna rank highly for their rich heritage rather than their current prowess.202020Similarly, the historic roots of psychology can be found in Leipzig (Rieber and Robinson, 2001). Cambridge and the London School of Economics are the only UK institutes on the list, but highly ranked. Columbia and Princeton complete the top 10. Further down the list, Heidelberg bests Yale and Stanford. Paris ranks above Johns Hopkins and Leiden, which never had an economics department, ahead of Berkeley.

Figure 6 thus reveals the dramatic shifts in the geography of teaching economics. When the generation of John Bates Clark studied economics, Heidelberg was the university to be and Knies the professor to consult.212121Perlman (2017) argues that German universities were ahead of the European competition because they were free from Church control and, after the Bismarck reforms, local state control. Balabkins (2017) adds that American students of economics preferred Germany to Great Britain because the latter emphasized theory and a doctrinal adherence to laissez-faire. Young economists today want to study with Knies’ great-great-great-grandstudents, who occupy the halls of the top universities in the USA.

Refer to caption
Figure 6: Universities that granted most degrees to Nobel Laureates and their professors.

4 Nobel candidates

Clarivate’s list of citation laureates includes many of world’s leading economists, although there are some surprising omissions too. All would be worthy Nobelists, and I suspect many will be. Indeed, Angrist, Card, Deaton, Engle, Fama, Granger, Hansen, Hart, Holmström, Kahneman, Krugman, Milgrom, Nordhaus, Romer, Sargent, Shiller, Sims, Thaler, Tirole, Williamson, and Wilson were citation laureates before winning the Nobel Prize. In Appendix A, I discuss the other citation laureates grouped by their place in the Nobel family tree, starting with the closest relatives.

4.1 The Nobel network in the future

The future network of Nobelists is likely to look much like the current network, as many candidates are closely related to previous winners and others most distantly. There are only three women among the candidates. New graphs may emerge around Gorman and Sargan, with the Gormanites more readily connected to the main tree than the Sarganites.

The top graph in Figure 7 shows the harmonic average distance from the Nobel candidates to the network in 2021. This is a measure of how central the candidate would be, should (s)he win. Brian Arthur, George Loewenstein, and Sam Peltzman are closest to the current network, Douglas Diamond, David Hendry, and Daniel Levinthal the furthest removed.

The bottom graph in Figure 7 shows the harmonic average distance from the Nobel candidates to the current Nobel laureates. Sam Peltzman now comes top, followed by Brian Arthur, and Blanchard, Dixit, Goldin, Hausman, and Hall in shared third place. 31 of the 56 candidates do not have a Nobel ancestor.

Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 7: Harmonic mean distance of Nobel candidates to the 2021 network (top panel) and to the Nobelists (bottom panel).

Figure 8 shows the change in the central ranking, based on the harmonic average distance, of Nobel Laureates should all candidates win. Milton Friedman, John Hicks and Tjalling Koopmans are closest to the candidates. Most Nobelists are not directly connected, but drop five places as others are propelled to greater centrality. Paul Samuelson, Robert Wilson and Franco Modigliani are furthest removed from the candidates, primarily because most of their Nobel-worthy students have won.

Refer to caption
Figure 8: Change in the harmonic centrality rank of selected Nobelists if all candidates win.

5 Discussion and conclusion

I show that the vast majority of winners of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences are connected in a network of professor-student relationships, and that this is likely to remain the case for years to come. The underlying data can be inspected and extended by anyone. A closer look at the wider network quickly dispels the notion of aggrieved economists, or their champions, that they did not want for lack of connections.

The two central figures in the Nobel network are Karl Knies and Wassily Leontief. Leontief needs no introduction (Samuelson, 2004; Baumol and ten Raa, 2009; Dietzenbacher and Lahr, 2004; Debresson, 2004; Duchin, 1995; Missemer, 2020). Who was Karl Knies? Having to raise this question indicates that his contributions to economics lie primarily in taking several young men—Herbert Baxter Adams, Eugen Böhm von Bawerk, John Bates Clark, Richard T. Ely, Richmond Mayo-Smith and Edwin Seligman—under his wings. Little has been written about Knies (Kobayashi, 2002; Schefold, 2008; Fullerton, 1998; Trautwein, 2005; Yagi, 2005), and there is no theorem, curve, lecture or medal named after him. Knies was a professor of public policy at the University of Freiburg from 1855 to 1865, and a professor of economics at the University of Heidelberg for the thirty years after, succeeded by Max Weber. He published on statistics, utility, political economy, railroads, and money and credit. Knies was part of the German Historical School, who argued for empiricism over theory, and thus at the losing end of the Methodenstreit (Louzek, 2011; Maki, 1997). Ely (1938) does not divulge much detail, but notes that Knies thought he did not receive the credit he deserved.222222The economics department at the University of Heidelberg is named after Alfred Weber, Max’ brother and successor. Knies was thus somewhat of an outlier, arguing for empirical analysis as the discipline of economics was turning towards theory. Knies would have welcomed the credibility revolution and the 2021 Nobel prize, shared by two of his descendants.

Leontief is best known as the father of input-output analysis (Polenske, 2004), a tool we now rarely see used at the cutting edge of economics. The main prize for heterodox economists is named after Leontief. The central role of Knies and Leontief in economic orthodoxy may thus come as a surprise—unless you realize that economics is at its best when the received wisdom is challenged (Roth, 2018).

If the central professors surprise, so do some of the key degree-granting universities: Berlin, Göttingen, Vienna and Heidelberg are not typically listed among the leading centres of research and education in economics. However, these universities did educate many of the Nobelists’ professors and their professors. Another surprising finding, the great economists of the past are not included in the family tree, but great scholars in just about any other discipline are (see discussion in the introduction). Putting these two findings together, it appears that during the first half of the 20th century, economists in Boston, Chicago and New York combined the ideas of earlier economists with the teaching methods of other disciplines and countries and so created the economics powerhouses we see today. Refugees from the Nazis—Haberler, Hayek, Hurwicz, Machlup, Marschak, von Mises, Morgenstern—played a key role in this, and ones who fled the Bolsheviks—Domar, Kuznets, Leontief and Marschak. See Scherer (2000) and Hagemann (2011) for an account.232323See Waldinger (2010) and Waldinger (2012), and references therein, for the impact of the Nazis on physics, chemistry and mathematics. Ely (1938, p.43) writes that ”[y]ou learn here [in Germany], and only here, how to do independent, real scientific work.” Ely (1938, p.40) notes that ”[a]lthough [Johannes Conrad of the University of Halle] was not a great original thinker he was a splendid teacher”, emphasizing the then disconnect between those who taught economics and those who moved its frontier.

The Nobel network has a gender-ratio that is even more biased towards men than the economics discipline as a whole.

The strong concentration of Nobelists around a small number of professors and universities is reminiscent of the strong concentration of top economists, top departments and top journals (Hamermesh, 2013; Torgler and Piatti, 2013).

I focus on professor-student relationships. There are, of course, many other types of interactions, including citation, co-supervision, shared supervisors, co-authoring—Arrow and Debreu (1954), for example—informal advice—John Maynard Keynes was the most senior figure in the Cambridge Circus, to which Joan Robinson also belonged—and seminars—in his autobiography, Herb Simon (1996) fondly reminisces the Cowles seminars, attended by in-house staff Marschak, Koopmans, Lange, Arrow, Klein, Hurwicz and Debreu and regular visitors Modigliani, Stigler, Friedman, Frisch and Haavelmo. Simon also describes a mind-shifting lunch with Carl Menger. Torgler and Piatti (2013, p. 77-78) document, in the words of Becker, Coase, Friedman and Samuelson, the contribution of Frank Knight to their intellectual development, in the absence of a formal mentoring relationship. Adding such relationships would only make the network more dense. It may well lead to a shift in network centrality. Data on informal contacts are, of course, much harder to obtain. Emmett (2009) demonstrates the power of such an analysis, and the effort required. Such trees are probably best limited to a certain department, as Emmett does, or a subfield of economics.

The descriptive analysis in this paper would be served with additional data on selected ancestors, such as discipline, ethnicity, religion. I identify a set of people who trained exceptional students, a set of people who did exceptional research, and the intersection of these sets. This should form a stepping stone to an analysis of what makes someone an exceptional researcher, an exceptional professor, or both. Contrasting the citation tree with the supervision tree would distinguish the two.

The measure, here defined, on incloseness to either the Nobel network or Nobel laureates can be calculated for individual researchers, departments, or editorial boards—and should be tested as a predictor for academic performance, career advancement, and the probability of winning the John Bates Clark Medal or indeed the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. Family trees could be constructed for similarly prestigious prizes in other disciplines to test whether tight clustering is unique to economics. Links between family trees—via Tinbergen to the Nobel Prize in Physics, via Nash to the Abel Prize, and via Knies to history, sociology and political science—would be worthy of study too. All that is deferred to future research.

References

  • (1)
  • Appelbaum (2017) Appelbaum, Binyamin. 2017. “Nobel in Economics Is Awarded to Richard Thaler.” New York Times.
  • Arrow and Debreu (1954) Arrow, Kenneth J., and Gerard Debreu. 1954. “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica, 22(3): 265–290.
  • Athey et al. (2007) Athey, Susan, Lawrence F. Katz, Alan B. Krueger, Steven Levitt, and James Poterba. 2007. “What Does Performance in Graduate School Predict? Graduate Economics Education and Student Outcomes.” American Economic Review, 97(2): 512–520.
  • Avent (2017) Avent, Ryan. 2017. “Richard Thaler wins the Nobel prize for economic sciences.” Economist.
  • Azoulay, Zivin and Wang (2010) Azoulay, P., J.S.G. Zivin, and J. Wang. 2010. “Superstar extinction.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(2): 549–589.
  • Balabkins (2017) Balabkins, Nicholas W. 2017. “American students in Germany, 1871-1914. A retrospective view.” Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomische Theorie, XXXII: 207–225.
  • Baumol and ten Raa (2009) Baumol, W.J., and T. ten Raa. 2009. “Wassily Leontief: In appreciation.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 16(3): 511–522.
  • Bavelas (1950) Bavelas, Alex. 1950. “Communication Patterns in Task-Oriented Groups.” The Journal of the Acoustical Society of America, 22(6): 725–730.
  • Boettke, Fink and Smith (2012) Boettke, P.J., A. Fink, and D.J. Smith. 2012. “The Impact of Nobel Prize Winners in Economics: Mainline vs. Mainstream.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 71(5): 1219–1249.
  • Borjas and Doran (2012) Borjas, George J., and Kirk B. Doran. 2012. “The Collapse of the Soviet Union and the Productivity of American Mathematicians*.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3): 1143–1203.
  • Bosquet and Combes (2017) Bosquet, Clément, and Pierre-Philippe Combes. 2017. “Sorting and agglomeration economies in French economics departments.” Journal of Urban Economics, 101: 27 – 44.
  • Breit and Hirsch (2009) Breit, William, and Barry T Hirsch. 2009. Lives of the Laureates: Twenty-Three Nobel Economists. Cambridge:MIT Press.
  • Chan and Torgler (2012) Chan, H.F., and B. Torgler. 2012. “Econometric fellows and Nobel Laureates in economics.” Economics Bulletin, 32(4): 3365–3377.
  • Chan and Torgler (2015) Chan, Ho Fai, and Benno Torgler. 2015. “The implications of educational and methodological background for the career success of Nobel laureates: an investigation of major awards.” Scientometrics, 102(1): 847–863.
  • Claes and de Ceuster (2013) Claes, A.G.P., and M.J.K. de Ceuster. 2013. “Estimating the economics Nobel Prize laureates’ achievement from their fame.” Applied Economics Letters, 20(9): 884–888.
  • Combes, Linnemer and Visser (2008) Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Laurent Linnemer, and Michael Visser. 2008. “Publish or peer-rich? The role of skills and networks in hiring economics professors.” Labour Economics, 15(3): 423 – 441.
  • David and Hayden (2012) David, Stephen V., and Benjamin Y. Hayden. 2012. “Neurotree: A Collaborative, Graphical Database of the Academic Genealogy of Neuroscience.” PLOS ONE, 7(10): 1–12.
  • Debresson (2004) Debresson, C. 2004. “Some highlights in the life of Wassily Leontief - an interview with Estelle and Wassily Leontief.” In Wassily Leontief And Input-Output Economics. 135–148.
  • Dietzenbacher and Lahr (2004) Dietzenbacher, E., and M.L. Lahr. 2004. “Wassily Leontief and input-output economics.” In Wassily Leontief And Input-Output Economics. 1–396.
  • Duchin (1995) Duchin, F. 1995. “In honor of Wassily Leontief’s 90th birthday.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 6(3): 267–269.
  • Ellison (2013) Ellison, Glenn. 2013. “How Does the Market Use Citation Data? The Hirsch Index in Economics.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(3): 63–90.
  • Ely (1938) Ely, Richard T. 1938. Ground Under Our Feet - An Autobiography. New York:MacMillan.
  • Emmett (2009) Emmett, Ross B. 2009. “The Chicago Workshop Model: Normalizing or Fragmenting Scientific Collaboration?” Arizona State University.
  • Fullerton (1998) Fullerton, R.A. 1998. “A prophet of modern advertising: Germany’s Karl Knies.” Journal of Advertising, 27(1): 51–66.
  • Gil-Mendieta and Schmidt (1996) Gil-Mendieta, Jorge, and Samuel Schmidt. 1996. “The political network in Mexico.” Social Networks, 18(4): 355 – 381.
  • Hagemann (2011) Hagemann, Harald. 2011. “European émigrés and the ‘Americanization’ of economics.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 18(5): 643–671.
  • Hamermesh (2013) Hamermesh, Daniel S. 2013. “Six decades of top economics publishing: Who and how?” Journal of Economic Literature, 51(1): 162–172.
  • Hamermesh and Schmidt (2003) Hamermesh, Daniel S., and Peter Schmidt. 2003. “The Determinants of Econometric Society Fellows Elections.” Econometrica, 71(1): 399–407.
  • Harford (2017) Harford, Tim. 2017. “Richard Thaler: how to change minds and influence people.” Financial Times.
  • Homan (1927) Homan, P.T. 1927. “John bates clark: Earlier and later phases of his work.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 42(1): 39–69.
  • Kobayashi (2002) Kobayashi, Jun. 2002. “Karl Knies’ conception of political economy.” In The German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics. , ed. Yuichi Shionoya. Abingdon:Routledge.
  • Laband and Piette (1994) Laband, David N., and Michael J. Piette. 1994. “Favoritism versus Search for Good Papers: Empirical Evidence Regarding the Behavior of Journal Editors.” Journal of Political Economy, 102(1): 194–203.
  • Leonard (2003) Leonard, T.C. 2003. “”A certain rude honesty”: John Bates Clark as a pioneering neoclassical economist.” History of Political Economy, 35(3): 521–558.
  • Louzek (2011) Louzek, M. 2011. “The Battle of Methods in Economics: The Classical Methodenstreit-Menger vs. Schmoller.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 70(2): 439–463.
  • Maki (1997) Maki, U. 1997. “Universals and the Methodenstreit: A re-examination of Carl Menger’s conception of economics as an exact science.” Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A, 28(3): 475–495.
  • Marchiori and Latora (2000) Marchiori, Massimo, and Vito Latora. 2000. “Harmony in the small-world.” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 285(3): 539 – 546.
  • McCarty (2000) McCarty, Marilu Hurt. 2000. The Nobel Laureates: How the Greatest Economic Minds of Our Time Shaped Modern Thought. New York:McGraw-Hill.
  • Medoff (2003) Medoff, Marshall H. 2003. “Editorial Favoritism in Economics?” Southern Economic Journal, 70(2): 425–434.
  • Minniti (2016) Minniti, M. 2016. “The Foundational Contribution to Entrepreneurship Research of William J. Baumol.” Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 10(2): 214–228.
  • Missemer (2020) Missemer, Antoine. 2020. “Wassily Leontief et la science économique.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 27(2): 339–341.
  • Offer and Söderberg (2016) Offer, Avner, and Gabriel Söderberg. 2016. The Nobel Factor: The Prize in Economics, Social Democracy, and the Market Turn. Princeton:Princeton University Press.
  • Oyer (2006) Oyer, Paul. 2006. “Initial Labor Market Conditions and Long-Term Outcomes for Economists.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(3): 143–160.
  • Partington (2017) Partington, Richard. 2017. “Nobel prize in economics awarded to Richard Thaler.” Guardian.
  • Perlman (2017) Perlman, Mark. 2017. “The rise and development of the American university system.” Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomische Theorie, XXXII: 13–122.
  • Polenske (2004) Polenske, K.R. 2004. “Leontief’s “magnificent machine” and other contributions to applied economics.” In Wassily Leontief And Input-Output Economics. 9–29.
  • Rader (1966) Rader, B.G. 1966. “Richard T. Ely: Lay spokesman for the social gospel.” Journal of American History, 53(1): 61–74.
  • Rieber and Robinson (2001) Rieber, Robert W., and David Robinson, ed. 2001. Wilhelm Wundt in History—The Making of a Scientific Psychology. Berlin:Springer.
  • Roth (2018) Roth, Alvin E. 2018. “Presidential Address.” Philadelphia.
  • Samuelson (2004) Samuelson, P.A. 2004. “A portrait of the master as a young man.” In Wassily Leontief And Input-Output Economics. 3–8.
  • Sanfeliu and Fu (1983) Sanfeliu, Alberto, and King-Sun Fu. 1983. “A distance measure between attributed relational graphs for pattern recognition.” IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, SMC-13(3): 353 – 362.
  • Schefold (2008) Schefold, B. 2008. “Knies, Karl Gustav Adolf (1821-1898).” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. , ed. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Basingstoke:Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Scherer (2000) Scherer, F. M. 2000. “The Emigration of German-Speaking Economists after 1933.” Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3): 614–626.
  • Simon (1996) Simon, Herbert A. 1996. Models of my life. Cambridge:MIT Press.
  • Solow and Murray (2015) Solow, R.M., and J. Murray. 2015. Economics for the curious: Inside the minds of 12 Nobel laureates.
  • Spencer and Macpherson (2015) Spencer, Roger W., and David A. Macpherson. 2015. Lives of the Laureates: Twenty-Three Nobel Economists. Cambridge:MIT Press.
  • Thies and Pecquet (2010) Thies, C.F., and G.M. Pecquet. 2010. “The shaping of a future president’s economic thought: Richard T. Ely and Woodrow Wilson at ”The Hopkins”.” Independent Review, 15(2): 257–277.
  • Torgler and Piatti (2013) Torgler, Benno, and Marco Piatti. 2013. A Century of American Economic Review. Basingstoke:Palgrave MacMillan.
  • Trautwein (2005) Trautwein, Hans-Michael. 2005. “Carl Knies’ Erörtungen über den Kredit.” Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomische Theorie, XX: 73–106.
  • Vane and Mulhearn (2005) Vane, H.R., and C. Mulhearn. 2005. The Nobel memorial laureates in economics: An introduction to their careers and main published works. Cheltenham:Edward Elgar.
  • Vitasek (2017) Vitasek, Kate. 2017. “Richard Thaler And The ’Human Factor’ In Economics.” Forbes.
  • Von Mises (2016) Von Mises, L. 2016. “The economist Eugen v. Bohm-Bawerk: On the occasion of the tenth anniversary of his death.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 19(2): 169–172.
  • Waldinger (2010) Waldinger, Fabian. 2010. “Quality Matters: The Expulsion of Professors and the Consequences for PhD Student Outcomes in Nazi Germany.” Journal of Political Economy, 118(4): 787–831.
  • Waldinger (2012) Waldinger, Fabian. 2012. “Peer Effects in Science: Evidence from the Dismissal of Scientists in Nazi Germany.” The Review of Economic Studies, 79(2): 838–861.
  • Waumans and Bersini (2016) Waumans, Michaël Charles, and Hugues Bersini. 2016. “Genealogical Trees of Scientific Papers.” PLOS ONE, 11(3): 1–15.
  • Weintraub (2011) Weintraub, E.R. 2011. “Retrospectives: Lionel W. McKenzie and the proof of the existence of a competitive equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(2): 199–215.
  • Yagi (2005) Yagi, K. 2005. “Karl Knies, Austrians, and Max Weber: A Heidelberg connection?” Journal of Economic Studies, 32(4): 314–330.
  • Yi (1996) Yi, Yun-Ae. 1996. “Margaret G. Reid: Life and achievements.” Feminist Economics, 2(3): 17–36.
  • Zuckerman (1996) Zuckerman, Harriet. 1996. Scientifc Elite—Nobel Laureates in the United States. New Brunswick:Transaction Publishers.

Appendix A Clarivate’s citation laureates

A.1 Students and academic siblings

Brian Arthur was a student of McFadden. He would be the first fifth-generation Nobelist.

Olivier Blanchard, Avinash Dixit and Robert Hall were all students of Solow. So are Anthony Atkinson, Martin Weitzman and Halbert White, who died before winning.

Claudia Goldin was a student of Fogel. Jerry Hausman was Mirrlees’ student. Dale Jorgenson was Leontief’s student, Michael Jensen a student of Miller, Sam Peltzman a student of Friedman and Stigler.

Harold Demsetz, a student of Frank Knight, is a sibling of Buchanan, Coase and Stigler. The late Gordon Tullock was a grandstudent of Knight.

Joshua Angrist and David Card were students of Orley Ashenfelter and so descend from Lewis and Modigliani. Angrist was advised by Card and advised Duflo. An Angrist-Card Nobel prize would make Duflo a third-generation Nobelist; she is already a fourth-generation one.

A.2 Grandstudents and academic cousins

Jordi Gali and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki are grandstudents of Solow, and Marc Melitz a great-grandstudent. All are candidate fourth-generation Nobelists, conditional on a Blanchard Nobel Prize.

Wesley Cohen is a grandstudent of Schelling, Stiglitz and Tobin. George Loewenstein is a grandstudent of Stiglitz, Mark Gertler Tobin’s.

Kenneth French is Fama’s grandstudent.

Matthew Rabin is a grandstudent of Maskin, Ariel Rubinstein of Arrow. The late Armen Alchian was Arrow’s academic nephew.

Philippe Aghion is a grandstudent of Lionel McKenzie, and so descends from Baumol, Cannan and Knies. Aghion further descends from Poisson. He is an academic cousin of Romer.

A.3 Distant relations

Robert Barro, Edward Lazear and Ariel Pakes were students of Zvi Griliches, and Steven Berry a grandstudent. They so descend from Ely. Jagdish Bhagwati, Gene Grossman, James Levinsohn and Marc Melitz also descend from Ely, via Charles Kindleberger. Anne Krueger is one of three woman among the Nobel candidates. Ely is her great-great-grandprofessor.

Colin Camerer is a great-great-great-grandstudent of John Dewey, Kuznets’ grandprofessor. Ernst Fehr descends from Lujo Brentano, Marschak’s grandprofessor.

Mark Granovetter is a great-grandstudent of Niels Bohr, who was Koopmans’ grandprofessor. Katarina Juselius descends from another one of Koopmans’ grandprofessors, Paul Ehrenfest. Peter Howitt is great-grandstudent of Koopmans. Elhanan Helpman descends from Ehrenfest via Houthakker.

Israel Kirzner was von Mises’ student. John List also descends from von Mises, and from Hayek, Hicks and Keynes. Hashem Pesaran descends from Keynes.

Charles Manski was a student of Franklin Fisher, sharing an ancestry with other prominent economists, including several Nobelists. Kevin Myers is a great-grandstudent of Schultz.

John Taylor descends from Everett Lindquist, and is thus related to Amos Tversky and via Henry Rietz to Gauss, Poisson and many Nobelists.

A.4 New trees

Manuel Arellano, David Hendry and Peter Phillips were students of Denis Sargan, and Pierre Perron a grandstudent. Sargan was a self-taught man, unconnected to the Nobel graph. There are other distinguished econometricians in his tree.

Richard Blundell, Stephen Bond. Martin Feldstein, John Moore and the prematurely deceased Alberto Alesina and Alan Krueger share a common ancestor in Terence Gorman. There are other prominent economists in the same family. Gorman is not connected to other Nobelists. Bond and Moore are also grandstudents of Frank Hahn, academic cousins of Imbens.

Stewart Myers and his student Raghuram Rajan descend from David Alhadeff. This could constitute a disjoint graph: Alhadeff obtained his PhD from Harvard shortly after World War II.242424The registrar argues that student-professor relationships are private information.

The late Stephen Ross252525PhD, 1970, Harvard and his student Douglas Diamond may form a disjoint graph, as would Wayne Fuller and his student David Dickey. Soren Johansen, David Kreps, Daniel Levinthal and Richard Posner would form their own trees.

Appendix B Matlab codes

  • Matlab code to scrape the ancestry of your favourite economist from Academic Tree and build her family tree.

  • Matlab code to build and analyze the data used in this paper.