On indication, strict monotonicity, and efficiency of projections
in a general class of path-based data envelopment analysis models
Abstract
Data envelopment analysis (DEA) theory formulates a number of desirable properties that DEA models should satisfy. Among these, indication, strict monotonicity, and strong efficiency of projections tend to be grouped together in the sense that, in individual models, typically, either all three are satisfied or all three fail at the same time. Specifically, in slacks-based graph models, the three properties are always met; in path-based models, such as radial models, directional distance function models, and the hyperbolic function model, the three properties, with some minor exceptions, typically all fail.
Motivated by this observation, the article examines relationships among indication, strict monotonicity, and strong efficiency of projections in the class of path-based models over variable returns-to-scale technology sets. Under mild assumptions, it is shown that the property of strict monotonicity and strong efficiency of projections are equivalent, and that both properties imply indication. This paper also characterises a narrow class of technology sets and path directions for which the three properties hold in path-based models.
keywords:
Data envelopment analysis , Directional distance function , Hyperbolic distance function , Indication , Strict monotonicity1 Introduction
Data envelopment analysis (DEA) is a non-parametric method measuring relative efficiency within a group of homogeneous units that use multiple inputs to produce multiple outputs. This paper focuses on DEA models that integrate an analytical description of the technology set and an efficiency measure into a single mathematical optimisation programme. The output of the programme for the unit under evaluation is its efficiency score and a certain benchmark/projection (a point on the frontier of the technology set) from which the score is derived. The concepts of efficiency score and projection enter the formulations of the so-called desirable properties of the models.
The most comprehensive lists of desirable properties are provided in Cooper, Park and Pastor (1999) and Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2009). These properties include indication of strong efficiency; homogeneity; strict/weak monotonicity; boundedness; unit invariance; and translation invariance. The selected DEA models are then classified on the basis of these criteria. In the works Halická and Trnovská (2021) and Halická, Trnovská and Černý (2024), the property of strongly efficient projection is added to the desirable properties and the fulfilment of all properties is studied within two wide classes of DEA models. It is observed that the three properties: indication, strong efficiency of projection, and strict monotonicity usually appear as a trio, either all three are fulfilled or not fulfilled in the given model.
This article examines the connection between the above mentioned three properties, the meaning and importance of which are as follows.
Indication:
The efficiency score is equal to one if and only if the evaluated unit is strongly efficient. This property allows revealing the strong efficiency of a unit just from the mere value of its efficiency score.
Strict monotonicity: An increase in any input or decrease of any output relative to the evaluated unit, holding other inputs as well as outputs constant, reduces the efficiency score. This property states that the measure of efficiency is fair – if a unit dominates another unit, then the former one has greater efficiency score. In the work Pastor et al. (1999), this property is interpreted as the sensitivity of the measure to changes in inputs or outputs.
Strong efficiency of projections: Projections generated by the model are strongly efficient. This property is sometimes called the property of efficient comparison. It states that the score is based on the comparison of the evaluated unit with a strongly efficient one, and therefore the value of the efficiency score is not overestimated. It could be viewed as an extension of the indication property (dealing with units with efficiency score equal to one) to any unit, and it could be alternatively formulated as: the efficiency score accounts for all sources of inefficiency if and only if the projection point is strongly efficient.
Note that the desirable properties of the measures over general technology sets were already formulated and analysed prior to the emergence of DEA – in the framework of economic production theory.111In the economic production theory, the measures of technical efficiency or inefficiency are called indices and the desirable properties of the indices are called axioms. The first work that formulated certain properties that an input (or output)-based efficiency measure should satisfy was the work of Färe and Lovell (1978). In this work, four properties were formulated, which, in addition to the three mentioned above, also included the property of homogeneity. Next, in Russell (1985) it was shown that, for a special type of measure, the efficient comparison property is redundant with respect to the other three properties. Certain objections were also raised regarding the unclear formulation of this property, worded as: “…comparison to efficient input vectors (the measure compares each feasible input vector to an efficient input vector).”
Later, in both areas, the list of desirable properties was expanded and the properties were examined not only in connection with input or output models, but also for graph measures of efficiency such as hyperbolic or additive measures (e.g. Pastor et al., 1999 and Russell and Schworm, 2011). In these and other works, the efficient comparison property was no longer mentioned, objections to the vagueness of the definition of this property were not reconsidered, and the validity of the conclusions of Russell (1985) about its redundancy for other types of measures was not verified.
In actual fact, DEA does provide mathematical tools for defining the projection and also supplies additional reasons to not neglecting the property of efficient comparison. Thanks to DEA, the models can be formulated as mathematical programming problems, and the relevant benchmarks/projections can be easily identified from their optimal solutions. This makes the efficient comparison property well-defined. Furthermore, the efficient comparison property (as well as the indication property) can be easily verified in the DEA models for each of the assessed units using the standard second-phase method. Nevertheless, the efficient comparison property is only seldom included in the list of desirable properties,222To the best of our knowledge, the efficient comparison property is explicitly listed among desirable properties of DEA models only in Halická and Trnovská (2021), Halická et al. (2024) and Pastor et al. (2022, p. 40), where in the last cited work this property appears as an extension of the standard ‘indication property’ under (E1b). and instead many authors settle for the weaker property of indication. However, the efficient comparison property and its verification in specific models are particularly important in DEA. Namely, DEA approximates the most widely used variable returns-to-scale technology using observed data coupled with the postulates of convexity and free disposability. This leads to polyhedral technologies whose large parts of the frontiers are not strongly efficient. Then, individual models projecting units on the frontier may derive scores from projections that are weakly but not strongly efficient.
There are two basic ways of searching for the benchmarks in DEA, leading to the classification of models into path-based models and slacks-based models introduced in the work Russell and Schworm (2018). As explained there, the slacks-based measures are expressed in terms of additive or multiplicative slacks for all inputs and outputs, and particular measures are generated by specifying the form of aggregation over the coordinate-wise slacks. On the other hand, the path-based measures are expressed in terms of a common contraction/expansion factor, and particular measures are generated by specifying the parametric path leading from the assessed unit towards the frontier of the technology set. In this class, the projection is uniquely determined as the point at which the path leaves the technology set. However, the slacks-based models may provide multiple benchmarks and hence it may not be apparent from which benchmark the efficient score is derived.
The desirable properties of slacks-based models over variable returns-to-scale (VRS) technology sets were analysed in Halická and Trnovská (2021) through a general scheme. The scheme encompassed all commonly used models, such as the Slacks-Based Measure (SBM) model of Tone (2001), the Russell Graph Measure model of Färe, Grosskopf and Lovell (1985), the Additive Model (AM) of Charnes et al. (1985), and the Weighted Additive Models (WAM) including the Range Adjusted Measure (RAM) model (Cooper, Park and Pastor, 1999) and the Bounded Adjusted Measure (BAM) model (Cooper et al., 2011). It was shown in Halická and Trnovská (2021) that the scores of these models are derived from benchmarks that may not be unique but are all strongly efficient, and the resulting score does not depend on the choice of the benchmark. As a consequence, all models in this class satisfy the indication and efficient comparison properties and, therefore, they all account for all sources of inefficiencies. The strict monotonicity property had to be individually assessed for models belonging to this scheme and was proven for all standard models with the exception of the BAM model, which only met the weak monotonicity.
Quite different results were obtained in the class of path-based models under VRS technology sets. These models include the radial BCC input or output-oriented models (Banker, Charnes and Cooper, 1984), the directional distance function (DDF) model (Chambers, Chung and Färe, 1996, 1998), and the hyperbolic distance function (HDF) model (Färe, Grosskopf and Lovell, 1985). Halická et al. (2024) analysed this class through a general scheme that depends on the parameters choices (convex functions and directional vectors) and covers all standard path-based models. The scheme allows for negative data.
The results showed that most models fail simultaneously all three properties of indication, strict monotonicity, and efficient comparison. However, the authors also presented very specific examples of path-based models that, in the case of technology sets with one input and one output, met all three properties. The simultaneous failure or success of the three properties invites the following questions,
-
(i)
to what extent the three properties are related;
-
(ii)
can one find sufficient conditions under which path-based models satisfy all three properties.
The aim of this article is to provide answers to these two questions.
With regard to the first question, it is fairly immediate that the property of efficient comparison implies the indication property; such an implication is also valid outside of the scheme of path-based models. However, the reverse implication is not apparent, and we will show that it is not even generally valid. Moreover, the connection between the efficient comparison property and the property of strict monotonicity is also unclear. In the framework of the general scheme of path-based models, we will show the equivalence of these two properties under mild assumptions. To the best of our knowledge, this equivalence will be identified and proved here for the first time.
Obtaining an answer to the second question can be important for practitioners — is it possible to attain the three desirable properties by a suitable choice of parameters of path-based models? An analysis outlined in Halická et al. (2024) indicates that appropriately modified range directions of Portela et al. (2004) tend to improve the properties of the model. These directions work well in single-input and single-output examples but not in all three-dimensional examples. More extensive numerical experiments with two inputs and two outputs carried out in Halická et al. (2024) show that these directions can significantly reduce the number of units not projected onto the strongly efficient frontier but cannot eliminate the presence of such units completely in general. Therefore, it seems that the problem partly stems from the characteristics of the VRS technology set generated by the data. In the second part of this article, we confirm this conjecture. We provide a characterisation of type of data, or equivalently, the type of technological set that, together with the aforementioned choice of directions, will ensure the three properties are met. We term this type of technology the ideal technology. We also offer a practical recipe to determine whether given data generates an ideal technology set.
The paper is organised as follows. The preliminaries required to accurately address the topics discussed in this article are outlined in Section 2. Section 3 examines the connections among the three desirable properties. In Section 4, particular directions and technology sets are outlined to ensure that all three properties are satisfied. Section 5 contains several numerical illustrations on real data. The concluding Section 6 summarises our theoretical findings and draws lessons for practitioners. A analyses the facial structure of a general VRS technology set, B gives equivalent characterizations of the ideal technology, and C contains the proof of Lemma 4.8.
2 Preliminaries
Let be the -dimensional Euclidean space and its non-negative orthant. Bold lowercase letters denote column vectors, and bold uppercase letters denote matrices. The superscript ⊤ denotes the transpose of a column vector or a matrix. For a vector , denotes its -th component, and hence . The symbol denotes a vector of ones.
We will consider a production process with inputs and outputs. For any two input-output vectors we will use the notation
-
•
if weakly dominates , i.e., and ;
-
•
if dominates , i.e, , , and ;
-
•
if strictly dominates , i.e., and .
2.1 Technology set
Consider a set of decision-making units () with observed input–output vectors . The input–output data of are arranged into the input and output matrices and , respectively. No assumption about the non-negativity of the data is made at this point. The non-negativity requirement may follow later from other assumptions placed on the models.
Based on the given data we consider the technology set
(1) |
corresponding to variable returns to scale (VRS). Note that the common non-negativity of is not imposed here. It follows from (1) that the set is closed, has a non-empty interior (denoted ) and its boundary satisfies . Elements of will be called units. By we denote a unit from to be evaluated.
The point , with elements , for and for , respectively, is called the ideal point of in DEA (see, e.g., Portela et al., 2004). The ideal point typically does not belong to , in which case it dominates every unit in . The technology set, for which , will be called trivial. Clearly, a trivial technology is an affine transformation of a non-negative orthant.
A unit is called strongly efficient333This is the well known Pareto–Koopmans efficiency. Some authors call such units Pareto efficient, or fully efficient - see the discussion in Cooper et al. (2007, p. 45). if no other unit in dominates , i.e., if the property that dominates yields . A unit is called weakly efficient if there is no unit in that strictly dominates .
Evidently, any strongly efficient unit is weakly efficient, and the weakly efficient units lie on the boundary of the technology set. The converse is also true: every unit on the boundary is weakly efficient because the definition of in (1) does not impose the non-negativity assumption on the units therein. The boundary is thus uniquely partitioned into the strongly efficient frontier containing all strongly efficient units and the remaining part , which consists of the weakly but not strongly efficient units. In this paper we will refer to the remaining part of the boundary as the weakly efficient frontier. Thus, we have and .
2.2 A general scheme for path-based models
We now recall the general scheme (GS) for path-based models from Halická et al. (2024). The scheme depends on both the choice of a prescription that defines the directional vector for each , and the choice of real functions and that together with their domains () and images () satisfy the following assumptions:
-
(A1)
with and with ;
-
(A2)
is smooth, concave, increasing and is smooth, convex, decreasing;
-
(A3)
;
-
(A4)
with if and otherwise; with .
The scheme is built on the technology set specified in (1) and is consequently also dependent on the matrices . Any choices of that satisfy the requirements mentioned above will be referred to as admissible parameters for a model in the GS scheme.
For a fixed choice of admissible parameters , the (path-based) GS model for assessment of is defined by
(2a) | ||||
(2b) | ||||
(2c) | ||||
(2d) |
The right-hand sides of (2b) and (2c), denoted by
(3) |
define a smooth path in the input-output space parametrized by .
For any choice of admissible parameters and each , the well-definedness of the programme and other useful properties of the path are established in Theorem 3.1 of Halická et al. (2024). According to this theorem, the path passes through the point at (i.e., ), and for decreasing values of it moves towards the boundary of gradually passing through points that dominate one another. This property of the path can be formally expressed as for , and we will refer to it as the monotonicity of the path with respect to . Finally, the path leaves at some , where , and is the optimal value in . The optimal value is called the efficiency score, or alternatively, the value of the efficiency measure for . The point on the path is called the projection of in the GS model.
2.3 Standard path-based models
It is easy to see that the well-known BCC input and output models (Banker et al., 1984), the hyperbolic distance function model (HDF) (Färe et al., 1985) as well as the generic directional distance function model (DDF) (Chambers et al., 1996, 1998) can be equivalently rewritten in the form of the general scheme (2). The scheme also includes the so-called generalised distance function model (GDF) introduced by Chavas and Cox (1999). These models, taken in conjunction with the usual assumptions on the positiveness of the data, will be called the standard path-based models. The corresponding parameterizations are shown in Table 1.
Model | ||
---|---|---|
BCC-I Banker et al. (1984) | ||
BCC-O Banker et al. (1984) | ||
DDF-g Chambers et al. (1996, 1998) | ||
HDF Färe et al. (1985) | ||
GDF Chavas and Cox (1999) |
The choice or for all leads to output or input oriented models, respectively. Among the standard path-based models, only DDF is formulated with general directional vectors. The BCC as well as the HDF use and / or . A generalisation of HDF towards general directions is introduced in Halická et al. (2024).
2.4 Properties of the general model
In Halická et al. (2024), the GS models are analysed in light of ten desired properties. Three of these merit further investigation. First, we recall the precise definitions of Halická et al. (2024) abridged to suit our needs here.
-
(ID)
Identification of strong efficiency. If for a given one has , then .
-
(PR)
Strong efficiency of projections. One has for each .
-
(MO)
Strict monotonicity. If for some , then .
Remark 2.1.
Note that (ID) is the ‘only if ’part of the property known in DEA as Indication: , if and only if . Unlike the ‘only if ’part of Indication, the ‘if ’part is universally satisfied by each model of the GS scheme (see Theorem 2 in Halická et al., 2024).444The ‘if ’and the ‘only if ’parts of Indication property are denoted as (P2a) and (P2b), respectively, in Halická et al. (2024).
Remark 2.2.
Let us briefly revisit the reasons for studying this triplet in more detail. The findings of Halická et al. (2024) show that none of the three properties are satisfied in the entire class of GS models. Moreover, there are examples of admissible model parameters, where all three properties are met, but it also appears that in most models the three properties fail simultaneously.
The relationships among the three properties for a particular GS model with a fixed set of admissible model parameters have been partially explored in Halická et al. (2024). Since (ID) is a restriction of (PR) to the weakly efficient frontier, it is easy to see that (PR) (ID), or equivalently,
NOT (ID) NOT (PR).555By NOT (XY) we understand that the model corresponding to the given configuration of admissible parameters violates the property (XY) at least at one . |
NOT (ID) occurs if and only if there is a unit on the weakly efficient frontier whose score is 1. Hence Halická et al. (2024, Theorem 4.20) further yields
NOT (ID) NOT (MO). |
Moreover, NOT (ID) arises whenever a unit on the weakly efficient frontier is associated with a positive direction (Halická et al., 2024, Theorem 3). The hierarchy of these properties, formulated by contra-position, is summarised in Figure 1.
It remains to establish the link between (PR) and (MO) and find examples, if any, where (ID) holds but (PR) and/or (MO) do not. This will be the subject of Section 3 with the main findings summarised in Figure 3.
A natural next question is what selection of admissible parameters leads to the success or failure of these characteristics. To this end, illustrative examples in Halická et al. (2024) indicate that the success could be connected with a special configuration of the data defining together with a special choice of unit-dependent directions based on Portela et al.’s range directions
(4) |
suitably modified to fit the GS scheme. This topic is addressed in Section 4.
3 Connections among (ID), (PR), and (MO)
Unless the model parameters are explicitly specified, the results of this section apply to a particular GS model with a fixed but arbitrarily chosen set of admissible model parameters. We are looking to investigate the consequences of (ID) on (PR) and (MO), as well as the connection between (PR) and (MO). In preparation for these tasks, we recall the necessary and sufficient conditions for (PR).
Theorem 3.1 (Halická et al., 2024, Theorem 4).
3.1 (ID) does not imply (PR)
The next example shows that (ID) may hold while (PR) fails for a certain selection of admissible model parameters.

Example 3.2.
Consider a one-input and one-output example with 7 DMUs: units , , , and on the boundary of and units , , and in its interior. Now, let us apply the DDF-g model with directions , . Figure 2 shows that all units belonging to (including generic ) are projected onto , and the only units that are projected onto themselves, and therefore have a score of 1, are the strongly efficient units from the line segment BC. Therefore, the property (ID) is satisfied. On the other hand, some units belonging to (e.g., ) are projected onto and therefore the property (PR) fails.666This example can be adapted to a more general case of inputs and one output, or one input and outputs over the so-called ‘ideal technology sets’ introduced later in Section 4. Note that a similar situation occurs for the HDF-g model with the Portela et al.’s range directions (4).
3.2 (MO) implies (PR)
Until now, we have considered the right-hand side of (2b) and (2c) as a (vector) function of for a fixed , which yields a path passing through the assessed unit ; see (3). To obtain a link between (MO) and (PR), it is helpful to consider the right-hand sides of (2b) and (2c) as functions of the assessed unit for a fixed . Observe that the right-hand sides in (3) depend explicitly on but the dependence may also be implicit via the directions .
Definition 3.3.
For each fixed we define the path-flow mapping as the function that maps each unit to the point .
Theorem 3.4.
If there exists such that and the path-flow mapping is continuous at , then the GS model does not meet the property of strict monotonicity (MO).
Proof.
Since , by Theorem 3.1 there exists an optimal solution of (2) and such that and
(5) |
Define
Each unit in is distinct from and dominates . Since and , the monotonicity of the path in implies that and . Therefore, the equations in (5) imply that and therefore also . Note that contains points that are arbitrarily close to . Now, by the continuity assumption, for there exists a unit such that . This implies that the vector inequalities and hold. Therefore, one also has
(6) |
By substituting (6) into (5) we get
(7) |
This yields that is a feasible solution for (GS)p, and hence one has . The strict monotonicity is violated because dominates and is different from but . ∎
Observe that Theorem 3.4 formulates a local property: if a point in is not projected onto , then one can find another point such that the pair fails to maintain strict monotonicity. Thus, the “local” formulation offers more flexibility than the following “global” corollary.
3.3 (PR) implies (MO)
The monotonicity of GS models is related to the monotonicity of the path-flow mapping , which we formalise next.
Definition 3.6.
We say that the path-flow mapping : is monotone on at if for any two units , in , one has
(8) |
If, in addition,
(9) |
we say that the path-flow mapping is strictly monotone on at .
Remark 3.7.
If for each the -th component of depends only on , and for each component depends only on , then the monotonicity property in Definition 3.6 simply means that and are nondecreasing in and , respectively. On the other hand, the strict monotonicity property in Definition 3.6 means that and are increasing in and , respectively.
Remark 3.8.
Note that if does not depend on , then the path-flow mapping is monotone on for any choice of and at any .
The next lemma will be useful for further analysis of strict monotonicity.
Lemma 3.9 (Halická et al., 2024, Lemma 3).
Let and be two units in with the corresponding optimal values and . If , then each optimal solution of (GS)o is a feasible solution of (GS)p and hence .
Let us note that the assumption of monotonicity of the path-flow mapping ensures the property of the so-called weak monotonicity of each model in the GS scheme as indicated by Lemma 3.9. To establish the strict monotonicity (MO) we will need the strict monotonicity of the path-flow mapping and property (PR). First, we formulate a local version of the assertion.
Theorem 3.10.
Suppose that units and in with the efficiency scores and , respectively, are projected onto the strongly efficient frontier. Suppose also that and that the path-flow mapping is strictly monotone at . Then .
Proof.
From the assumptions of the theorem it follows that . This, by Lemma 3.9 implies that . Assume, by contradiction, that . Denote by an optimal solution for (GS)o. Obviously, the same pair also represents an optimal solution for (GS)p. Since the model projects and onto the strongly efficient frontier, by Theorem 3.1 the inequalities (2b) and (2c) in (GS)o and (GS)p are binding, that is,
and | (10) |
(11) |
By comparing the right-hand sides of (10) and (11), we get
(12) |
This is in contradiction with the assumption of strict monotonicity of the path-flow mapping at , according to which holds. ∎
Theorem 3.10, too, is formulated locally, i.e., if two ordered units are both projected onto , then their efficiency scores are strictly ordered. The local formulation once again offers more flexibility than the following global corollary.
Corollary 3.11.
The results of this section are summarised in Figure 3.
4 Specific technology sets and direction vectors ensuring (PR)
We recall that the GS models fail all three properties (ID), (PR), and (MO) when the directions are positive. Nonetheless, there exist simple examples, where the GS models with specific directions over specific technology sets project every unit from onto the strongly efficient frontier.


Example 4.1.
Consider a one-input, one-output technology set generated by three units as depicted in Figure 4. DDF-g paths (where and ) with the range directions and connect the units from with the ideal point for this technology as seen in the left diagram of Figure 4. In the case of HDF-g paths (where and ) the range directions were modified to and to pass through the ideal point as shown in the right panel of Figure 4. In both cases, the models project units onto the strongly efficient boundary consisting of the line segments and .
In this section, we will generalise the two GS models presented in Example 4.1 with the aim of fully characterising those technology sets and directions under which the GS model yields the strong efficiency of projections. In doing so, the ideal point of the technology set will play an important role.
4.1 GS range directions
As shown in Figure 4, the paths in Example 4.1 connect units from to the ideal point , which ensures that the units are projected onto the strongly efficient boundary. Inspired by this example, we now characterise those directions for which the corresponding path for passes through the ideal point at an arbitrarily chosen . The choice of common for all units in then allows us to obtain comparable scores whose common lower bound is . The proof follows by a simple calculation and is therefore omitted.
Recall that denotes the ideal point of and that for fixed and , the path is determined by the evaluated unit and the direction as detailed in Subsection 2.2.
Lemma 4.2.
Fix , satisfying assumptions (A1)–(A4) and of the form (1). For and , the following are equivalent.
-
(i)
The path runs through the ideal point at , i.e., .
-
(ii)
The direction vector of satisfies
(13)
Moreover, if either of these conditions holds, then .
We will call the direction vector defined by (13) the GS range direction.
In the case of DDF-g models, we have , , and . On selecting , the GS range directions coincide with the range directions (4) of Portela et al. (2004). In the case of HDF-g models, we have , , and , hence must be chosen positive. The value yields and .
Remark 4.3.
For , the GS range direction for satisfies and therefore the programme is well defined. On the other hand, if , then the GS range direction for vanishes and the corresponding programme is not well defined. However, since is the (only) strongly efficient unit in , we can set by definition for this point.
The next lemma shows that the choice of the GS range direction ensures that both and , the and components of the path , passes through the relative interior of the line segments connecting with and with , respectively.
Lemma 4.4.
Let , and be the optimal value of in the model with the GS range direction. Then, for each there exist and such that
(14) |
Proof.
For each we have and hence and . Therefore,
(15) |
Finally, a simple computation yields
from which the claim of the lemma follows. ∎
Figure 4 illustrates that the paths containing the ideal point of a given technology set project all units onto the strongly efficient frontier. This property, whilst true in two-dimensional technology sets, no longer holds for all higher-dimensional technologies. Indeed, the two-input, one-output example in Halická et al. (2024, Example 2 and Figure 3) shows that the DDF-g model with the GS range directions projects a unit from onto itself. Halická et al. (2024) conducted further numerical experiments on real data consisting of 30 units, 2 inputs, and 2 outputs, with some negative output values. Their analysis contrasts the so-called proportional directions , of Kerstens and Van de Woestyne (2011) with the GS range directions for four different choices of the path function . In their analysis, the GS range directions yield a significantly smaller proportion of units not projected onto the strongly efficient frontier but do not eliminate such units completely. Therefore, even though the GS range directions ensure the passage of all paths through the ideal point, this alone is not enough to guarantee that units are projected onto the strongly efficient frontier in the case of higher-dimensional technology sets.
4.2 Ideal technology sets
It is obvious that to ensure the fulfilment of (PR) using GS range directions, it will be necessary to limit ourselves to a certain subclass of technology sets. To specify the properties of the subclass, it turned out that the facial structure of the technology as a polyhedral set will play an important role. Some characteristics of the facial structure of (10), as well as all necessary terms, are included in Appendix A. The results of the current section will finally show that the GS range directions will guarantee projecting onto strongly efficient frontier if and only if we restrict ourselves to technology sets specified in the following definition.
Definition 4.5.
A technology set of the form (1) is called an ideal technology if each unit from the weakly efficient boundary of has at least one component in common with the ideal point of , i.e.,
(16) |
It is easy to see that the technology sets (1) with only one input and one output, as in Example 4.1, are ideal. A trivial example of an ideal technology in any dimension is the trivial technology, i.e., the technology containing its ideal point . The trivial technology is a polyhedral cone with the vertex at the ideal point. Its facets — faces of full dimension — are parallel to the orthant hyperplanes. The vertex is the only strongly efficient unit of the trivial technology set.
We now provide examples of ideal and non-ideal technology sets.
Example 4.6.
Consider two inputs and one output example with three DMU‘s: , , , see Figure 5. All three units and are strongly efficient and the triangle forms a strongly efficient frontier for the technology generated by these three DMU’s. Apparently . It is seen that the closure of consists of three facets, each determined by one of the hyperplanes , or , and thus this technology set satisfies the property (16).

Example 4.7.
Consider again two inputs and one output example with another three DMU‘s: , , , see Figure 6. Also in this example all three points are strongly efficient and triangle forms a strongly efficient frontier for the technology generated these three DMU’s. Apparently . In this case, the closure of consists of six facets, where only three of them correspond to hyperplanes , or . Points from (the relative) interiors of the other three facets satisfy , and and hence property (16) is not satisfied.

Theorem B.1 provides equivalent characterisations of ideal technologies. It shows that every ideal technology is obtained by ‘tapering off’ some part of the trivial technology near the ideal point by means of a finite number of hyperplanes in such a way that all edges of the trivial technology are preserved sufficiently far from its vertex (Figure 5). A technology is not ideal precisely when at least one of the edges of the trivial technology is completely missing. Figure 5 gives an example of a non-ideal technology, where all three edges of the induced trivial technology are absent. Item iv of Theorem B.1 also provides a tool for the practical recognition of whether a given set of DMUs generates an ideal technology or not.
The following lemma is an important instrument for developing the main results in Subsection 4.3. It characterises the relative boundary of unbounded faces of an ideal technology . Its proof is found in C. The necessary material describing the facial structure of as a polyhedral set is collected in A and B.
Lemma 4.8.
Let be an ideal technology set. For we introduce index sets and and denote their cardinality by and , respectively. Then belongs either to , or to the relative interior of the dimensional face of given by
(17) |
4.3 GS models with GS range directions over ideal technology sets
The next theorem shows that the GS models with GS range directions meet the property (PR) for any feasible if and only if is ideal.
Theorem 4.9.
In the GS model with the GS range directions (13), the following are equivalent.
-
(i)
All units in are projected onto the strongly efficient frontier.
-
(ii)
is an ideal technology set.
Proof.
i ii Arguing by contradiction, assume that is not an ideal technology. This means that does not have the property (16) and therefore there exists such that and . Then the formulas in (13) imply . Now, by Theorem 4.2 of Halická et al. (2024), the positivity of the direction at implies . Hence is identical to its projection and (PR) is not satisfied.
ii i If (that is, if is the trivial technology), then the choice of the GS range direction guarantees that each is projected on , which is the only strongly efficient unit in , and hence the theorem holds. Obviously .
Now consider the case . Let and be the index sets of defined in Lemma 4.8, which can also be empty. According to Lemma 4.8, either belongs to the relative interior of or is strongly efficient. In the latter case, there is nothing to prove. Therefore, assume that and is its score. From the prescription (13) of the GS range direction it follows that and if and only if and respectively. This implies that the path for decreasing values of stays in until it reaches the relative boundary of at some . This allows us to apply Lemma 4.4 according to which there exist and such that and satisfy (14). From this follows that and if an only if and , resp., hence and is the index set also for . We apply Lemma 4.8 again, this time to a point that we know is from the relative boundary of and hence is strongly efficient and . ∎
Theorem 4.10.
Let be an ideal technology set with . Then the GS model with the GS range direction meets the property of strict monotonicity (MO).
Proof.
According to Theorem 4.9, the GS model with the GS range direction satisfies (PR), and hence by Corollary 3.11 it suffices to prove that the path-flow mapping is strictly monotone on at any . In our case, the vector function has a property that depends only on and depends only on , and hence by Remark 3.7 it suffices to prove that and are increasing in and , respectively. Obviously, the path-flow mapping is strictly monotone on at . For the case we use Lemma 4.4 according which there exist and such that
(18) |
and hence the derivative of with respect to is positive. The proof for is analogous. ∎
Remark 4.11.
It is easy to see that the GS model with the GS range direction does not meet the property (MO) over the trivial technology . By Lemma 4.2 the path generated by directions (13) passes through at and since this point belongs to , it holds . Hence, the efficiency score of each unit is equal to the same value . Note that this is consistent with the results of Section 3.3: since for any the corresponding projection is equal to the same value , the path-flow mapping is not strictly monotone on at .
5 Numerical examples
This section documents the ability of individual path-based DEA models to project units onto the strongly efficient frontier in different real datasets. We consider two basic settings for the function : linear, which leads to the DDF-g models, and hyperbolic, which leads to the HDF-g models. As direction vectors, we have selected vectors from groups analysed by Halická et al. (2024); their description can be found in Table 2.
Notation | Reference | ||
---|---|---|---|
(G1) | Kerstens and Van de Woestyne (2011) | ||
(G2) | Halická et al. (2024) | ||
(G3) | Portela et al. (2004) | ||
(G4) | Aparicio et al. (2013) |
The numerical experiments look at 10 real datasets (see Table 3) that have previously been used in various case studies. The descriptive statistics for each dataset can be found in D. It should be noted that Dataset 4 contains negative data, and that the two undesirable outputs in Dataset 10 were treated as inputs. Furthermore, the three datasets (i.e., 2, 8, 9) that did not initially contain input or output values were supplemented by input or output values equal to unity for all units, respectively. The datasets vary in the density of efficient units, with the ratio of strongly efficient units to the total number of units ranging from 22% for Dataset 10 to 57% for Dataset 6.
Dataset | total/eff DMUs | density | inputs | outputs | source |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 20/9 | 45.0% | 3 | 2 | Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2007) |
2 | 139/32 | 23.0% | 4 | 0 | Toloo and Kresta (2014) |
3 | 31/11 | 35.5% | 3 | 2 | Juo et al. (2015) |
4 | 30/9 | 30.0% | 2 | 2 | Tone et al. (2020) |
5 | 13/5 | 38.5% | 1 | 3 | Talluri and Yoon (2000) |
6 | 28/16 | 57.1% | 4 | 2 | Ray (2008) |
7 | 31/15 | 48.4% | 2 | 3 | Xiong et al. (2019) |
8 | 46/11 | 23.9% | 0 | 4 | Foroughi (2011) |
9 | 15/4 | 26.7% | 0 | 6 | Liu et al. (2011) |
10 | 92/20 | 21.7% | 3+2 | 1 | Färe et al. (2007) |
We have applied the DDF-g ( , , ) and HDF-g models ( , , ), combined with directions (G1), (G2), (G3), and (G4) to all 10 datasets listed in Table 3. For numerical computations we have utilised a Matlab implementation of the CVX modelling system (see Grant and Boyd, 2014, Grant and Boyd, 2008) to solve convex programmes. After the efficiency evaluation using (2), we have applied the standard second phase method (described for path-based models by programme (18) in Halická et al., 2024) to determine the number of units projected onto the strongly efficient frontier. The results are shown in Table 4.
DDM-g | HDM-g | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dataset | (G1) | (G2) | (G3) | (G4) | (G1) | (G2) | (G3) | (G4) |
1 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 | 50.0 |
2 | 22.3 | 53.2 | 27.3 | 22.3 | 23.0 | 53.2 | 27.3 | 23.7 |
3 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 | 35.5 |
4 | 40.0 | 70.0 | 66.7 | 43.3 | 43.3 | 76.7 | 66.7 | 53.3 |
5 | 53.9 | 61.5 | 53.9 | 61.5 | 46.2 | 61.5 | 53.9 | 61.5 |
6 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 | 57.1 |
7 | 61.3 | 67.7 | 58.1 | 58.1 | 61.3 | 64.7 | 58.1 | 58.1 |
8 | 23.9 | 80.4 | 52.2 | 23.9 | 23.9 | 80.4 | 52.2 | 23.9 |
9 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 | 26.7 |
10 | 22.8 | 22.8 | 21.7 | 21.7 | 22.8 | 23.9 | 21.7 | 22.8 |
We can see that four of the datasets (i.e., 1, 3, 6, 9) are resistant to direction selection — the same number of units is projected onto the strongly efficient frontier regardless of our choice of directions. A possible explanation for this phenomenon is that the units projected onto are so close to this part of the boundary that even the choice of the direction leading to the ideal point cannot prevent their projections onto . To a lesser extent, this is also true for datasets 5 and 10. In all other datasets, the GS range direction (G2) outperforms, often significantly, the remaining directions.
In our numerical experiment, the GS range direction achieves the highest number of strongly efficient projections in each dataset. However, as one can see on the example of Datasets 3, 9, and 10, even the the best direction may project majority of the inefficient units onto . Their scores do not capture all the inefficiencies. Therefore, it is important to bear this in mind when interpreting the results of path-based models.
6 Conclusions
The paper analyses connections among three desirable properties of DEA models: indication, strict monotonicity, and strong efficiency of projections. For a correct interpretation of the results of a model, it is important to know whether the model meets these characteristics. A good understanding of the properties allows one to decide whether the units with a score equal to one were correctly identified as strongly efficient, whether the score of any unit from captures all sources of inefficiency, and whether the obtained scores of the units allow a fair comparison of inefficient units with each other. If it is known that one of the properties is not met in the model, it may be necessary to perform further analyses or exercise care when interpreting the results of the model.
This article focuses on path-based models which are characterised by the fact that individual models, with some exceptions, do not fulfil even one of the three properties. Our findings are summarised in Figure 7.
The article shows that the common practice of replacing the property (PR) with the property (ID) is not justified, in general. This is evidenced by example 3.2, where the model satisfies (ID) but not (PR). On the other hand, it was shown (surprisingly to us) that the property (PR) is equivalent to the property (MO) under mild assumptions. Nonetheless, the verification of these two properties has a different flavour: while the property (MO) is usually verified analytically for a specific model (i.e., it is proved theoretically as a global property, even outside the class of path-based models), the validation of the property (PR) for a given unit in can be performed numerically by applying the standard second phase.
In this paper, we also characterise the cases that ensure the three properties are met. Such models are characterised by the GS range directions (13) and the data that generate an ideal technology (Definition 4.5). The latter requirement can be easily verified in practice using Theorem B.1(iv). Taken as a whole, our analysis yields the following recommendations for DEA practitioners.
-
1.
When using path-based models, it must be assumed that the model does not meet the indication, strict monotonicity, and efficiency of the projections. This means that some units may not be projected onto the strongly efficient boundary. Therefore, if one wishes to know whether the obtained score captures all sources of inefficiency, it is necessary to apply the second-phase to identify the non-included slacks.
-
2.
To increase the number of units projected onto the strongly efficient frontier, it is advisable to use the GS range directions. These directions ensure that all units are projected onto the strongly efficient frontier in the case of single input, single output data, and more generally for all data configurations that correspond to an ideal technology. Although higher-dimensional data typically do not result in an ideal technology, empirical evidence suggests that the GS range directions perform no worse and in some datasets significantly better than their alternatives.
Acknowledgements
The authors thank three anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments. The research of the first two authors was supported by the APVV-20-0311 project of the Slovak Research and Development Agency and the VEGA 1/0611/21 grant administered jointly by the Scientific Grant Agency of the Ministry of Education, Science, Research and Sport of the Slovak Republic and the Slovak Academy of Sciences.
Appendix A Polyhedral characteristics of the VRS technology set
As is well known, every polyhedral set can be expressed as the intersection of a limited number of half-spaces (see, e.g., Klee, 1959, or Rockafellar, 1970). In the case of the variable returns-to-scale technology set defined in (1), the half-spaces must be of the form
(19) |
In order to exclude redundant half-spaces, we consider only the facet-defining half-spaces for which
(20) |
is a facet of the polyhedron .777 The relative boundary of the facet defining half-space is a supporting hyperplane to at any point of the corresponding facet. We also introduce notation and for the special half-spaces
(21) |
and denote the corresponding facets by
(22) |
for and . The following lemma lists some known results about polyhedral sets applied to the facial structure of general VRS technologies defined by (1). These results are helpful in the proof of Theorem B.1.
Lemma A.1.
Any technology set defined by (1) is the intersection of a finite number of facet-defining half-spaces with and and its boundary is the union of the corresponding facets. Moreover, the following statements hold.
-
(a)
Facets with and are bounded and their union forms .
-
(b)
Facets whose vector contains at least one zero component are unbounded and their union is the closure of .
-
(c)
Each of the special half-spaces in (21) is facet-defining. Furthermore, the corresponding facets , are unbounded.
-
(d)
Every point satisfies and .
Appendix B Characterisation of ideal technology sets
The next theorem formulates six equivalent characterisations of ideal technology sets, of which the property vi was previously used as the definition (see (16) in Subsection 4.2). By comparing the properties of the general technology set presented in Lemma A.1 with the characterisation in Theorem B.1 i, we see that ideal technologies are those sets whose weak facets are precisely the special facets and .
Theorem B.1.
For a technology set defined by (1), the following are equivalent.
-
(i)
is the intersection of the half-spaces and and a finite number of facet defining half-spaces with positive and .
-
(ii)
The closure of the weakly efficient boundary can be represented as .
-
(iii)
The weakly efficient boundary can be represented as .
-
(iv)
For each of the input–output coordinates, there is a generating unit DMUj, , which coincides with the ideal point except perhaps in this one coordinate. More formally, for each there exists a such that and ; and for each there exists a such that and , .
-
(v)
For each of the input–output coordinates, there is a point in the technology set that coincides with the ideal point except perhaps in this one coordinate. More formally, for each there exists a such that and for each there exists a such that .
-
(vi)
Each point on the weakly efficient frontier coincides with the ideal point in at least one component. More formally, for each there exists a
Proof.
The proof scheme is shown in Figure 8.
- i ii
- ii i
-
ii iii
Since , the claim follows.
-
iii iv
The claim iii implies that contains facets . These facets are mutually orthogonal and, hence, the intersections of any of these facets form edges (one-dimensional faces) of . Each of these edges contains a vertex of the form described in iv. Since the vertices of belong to the set of units generating , the assertion iv holds.
-
iv v
This implication is trivial.
-
v vi
Assume by contradiction that v holds and that there exists such that . Since is weakly but not strongly efficient, due to free disposability, there exists a unit in dominating in exactly one component. Without loss of generality, assume that it is the -th input component, i.e., one has for some . Note that v implies for some . For define
Clearly for all . For sufficiently small, we have
which contradicts .
- vi ii
Appendix C Proof of Lemma 4.8
Trivially, (see definitions in (22)). Since the normals of the facets and are linearly independent, is the - dimensional face of . The (relative) boundary of each face consists of faces of lower dimensions. Theorem B.1i implies that the relative boundary of consists of two types of - dimensional faces: the first one is expressed as the intersections of with one of the facets , or , ; the second one is expressed as the intersections of with one of the faces generated by where , .
From the definition of and it follows that does not belongs to any of the faces of the first type. Therefore, is either an interior point of or it belongs to a face of type , which due to the positiveness of the vectors belongs to the strongly efficient frontier of . The lemma is proved.
Appendix D Descriptive statistics of datasets used in Section 5
min | 27.00 | 115.00 | 2584.00 | 5765.00 | 3286.00 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
max | 1043.00 | 436.00 | 17412.00 | 223340.00 | 39653.00 |
mean | 403.10 | 248.80 | 8170.90 | 81723.00 | 14413.40 |
std. dev. | 381.20 | 96.37 | 5130.93 | 82604.64 | 11747.93 |
min | 0.00 | 6521.00 | 0.000 | 1.192 |
---|---|---|---|---|
max | 508203.00 | 36062.00 | 1213.000 | 1.804 |
mean | 225635.85 | 15382.37 | 976.281 | 1.413 |
std. dev. | 152560.30 | 7652.33 | 480.586 | 0.151 |
min | 24930.00 | 204.00 | 489.00 | 2203.00 | 60552.00 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
max | 2781454.00 | 8804.00 | 78284.00 | 431255.00 | 1912741.00 |
mean | 710482.84 | 3811.26 | 14003.23 | 134856.35 | 560873.87 |
std. dev. | 684169.90 | 2608.07 | 15703.33 | 135245.53 | 537324.60 |
min | 418242.00 | 1319.0 | -561965.00 | -0.25830 |
---|---|---|---|---|
max | 16655569.00 | 634436.0 | 3092358.00 | 3.53714 |
mean | 3705789.57 | 102759.1 | 4.26691.37 | 0.32565 |
std. dev. | 3807894.37 | 135690.5 | 653124.35 | 0.79420 |
min | 4.0 | 0.025 | 6.00 | 0.50 |
---|---|---|---|---|
max | 12.5 | 1.250 | 115.00 | 2.90 |
mean | 7.6 | 0.420 | 44.92 | 1.22 |
std. dev. | 2.6 | 0.450 | 35.16 | 0.73 |
min | 4067.00 | 62.00 | 241.00 | 587.00 | 2943.00 | 65.00 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
max | 80627.00 | 2381.00 | 5678.00 | 18624.00 | 133796.00 | 5346.00 |
mean | 28690.43 | 838.18 | 2140.25 | 7075.04 | 4.3555.86 | 1298.61 |
std. dev. | 20279.43 | 653.57 | 1442.54 | 5352.85 | 3.4877.86 | 1183.87 |
min | 1.0 | 367.70 | 31.26 | 39.78 | 124.63 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
max | 65.9 | 3738.00 | 3209.72 | 1887.45 | 21801.65 |
mean | 22.7 | 1609.20 | 1132.71 | 0.738.08 | 5383.30 |
std. dev. | 18.7 | 896.72 | 812.36 | 501.28 | 5357.41 |
min | 1.18 | 10.82 | 163.0 | 11.29 |
---|---|---|---|---|
max | 3.87 | 55.65 | 718.0 | 139.02 |
mean | 1.81 | 25.05 | 474.7 | 56.52 |
std. dev. | 0.72 | 11.21 | 138.99 | 31.12 |
min | 6.88 | 12.06 | 1.15 | 2.68 | 11.22 | 15.97 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
max | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 |
mean | 36.56 | 47.80 | 16.10 | 19.08 | 43.67 | 48.54 |
std. dev. | 32.09 | 30.15 | 26.25 | 25.51 | 22.38 | 26.82 |
min | 39349184.0 | 39.0 | 1892407000000 | 1293.20 | 423.05 | 166616000 |
max | 750024804.0 | 535.0 | 175688406305600.0 | 252344.60 | 72524.10 | 18212069000 |
mean | 240000014.7 | 185.2 | 47104363123213.0 | 40745.19 | 17494.02 | 4686524843 |
std. dev. | 146352514.9 | 110.9 | 39982238625707.7 | 48244.78 | 16190 |
References
- Aparicio et al. (2013) Aparicio, J., Pastor, J.T., Ray, S.C., 2013. An overall measure of technical inefficiency at the firm and at the industry level: The ‘lost profit on outlay’. European Journal of Operational Research 226, 154–162.
- Banker et al. (1984) Banker, R.D., Charnes, A., Cooper, W.W., 1984. Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Management Science 30, 1078–1092. doi:10.1287/mnsc.30.9.1078.
- Chambers et al. (1996) Chambers, R.G., Chung, Y., Färe, R., 1996. Benefit and distance functions. Journal of Economic Theory 70, 407–419.
- Chambers et al. (1998) Chambers, R.G., Chung, Y., Färe, R., 1998. Profit, directional distance functions, and Nerlovian efficiency. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 98, 351–364. doi:10.1023/A:1022637501082.
- Charnes et al. (1985) Charnes, A., Cooper, W.W., Golany, B., Seiford, L., Stutz, J., 1985. Foundations of data envelopment analysis for Pareto-Koopmans efficient empirical production functions. Journal of Econometrics 30, 91–107. doi:10.1016/0304-4076(85)90133-2.
- Chavas and Cox (1999) Chavas, J.P., Cox, T.L., 1999. A generalized distance function and the analysis of production efficiency. Southern Economic Journal 66, 294–318.
- Cooper et al. (1999) Cooper, W.W., Park, K.S., Pastor, J.T., 1999. RAM: A range adjusted measure of inefficiency for use with additive models, and relations to other models and measures in DEA. Journal of Productivity Analysis 11, 5–42. doi:10.1023/a:1007701304281.
- Cooper et al. (2011) Cooper, W.W., Pastor, J.T., Borras, F., Aparicio, J., Pastor, D., 2011. BAM: A bounded adjusted measure of efficiency for use with bounded additive models. Journal of Productivity Analysis 35, 85–94.
- Cooper et al. (2007) Cooper, W.W., Seiford, L.M., Tone, K., 2007. Data Envelopment Analysis: A Comprehensive Text with Models, Applications, References and DEA-Solver Software. Springer US. doi:10.1007/978-0-387-45283-8.
- Davtalab-Olyaie et al. (2015) Davtalab-Olyaie, M., Roshdi, I., Partovi Nia, V., Asgharian, M., 2015. On characterizing full dimensional weak facets in DEA with variable returns to scale technology. Optimization 64, 2455–2476. doi:10.1080/02331934.2014.917305.
- Färe et al. (1985) Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Lovell, C.A.K., 1985. The Measurement of Efficiency of Production. Springer Netherlands. doi:10.1007/978-94-015-7721-2.
- Färe et al. (2007) Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Pasurka Jr, C.A., 2007. Environmental production functions and environmental directional distance functions. Energy 32, 1055–1066.
- Färe and Lovell (1978) Färe, R., Lovell, C.A.K., 1978. Measuring the technical efficiency of production. Journal of Economic Theory 19, 150–162. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(78)90060-1.
- Foroughi (2011) Foroughi, A., 2011. A note on “a new method for ranking discovered rules from data mining by dea”, and a full ranking approach. Expert Systems with Applications 38, 12913–12916.
- Grant and Boyd (2008) Grant, M., Boyd, S., 2008. Graph implementations for nonsmooth convex programs, in: Blondel, V., Boyd, S., Kimura, H. (Eds.), Recent Advances in Learning and Control. Springer-Verlag Limited. Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences, pp. 95–110. http://stanford.edu/~boyd/graph_dcp.html.
- Grant and Boyd (2014) Grant, M., Boyd, S., 2014. CVX: Matlab software for disciplined convex programming, version 2.1. http://cvxr.com/cvx.
- Halická and Trnovská (2021) Halická, M., Trnovská, M., 2021. A unified approach to non-radial graph models in data envelopment analysis: Common features, geometry, and duality. European Journal of Operational Research 289, 611–627. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2020.07.019.
- Halická et al. (2024) Halická, M., Trnovská, M., Černý, A., 2024. A unified approach to radial, hyperbolic, and directional efficiency measurement in data envelopment analysis. European Journal of Operational Research 312, 298–314.
- Juo et al. (2015) Juo, J.C., Fu, T.T., Yu, M.M., Lin, Y.H., 2015. Profit-oriented productivity change. Omega 57, 176–187.
- Kerstens and Van de Woestyne (2011) Kerstens, K., Van de Woestyne, I., 2011. Negative data in dea: a simple proportional distance function approach. Journal of the Operational Research Society 62, 1413–1419.
- Klee (1959) Klee, V., 1959. Some characterizations of convex polyhedra. Acta Mathematica 102, 79–107. doi:10.1007/BF02559569.
- Liu et al. (2011) Liu, W., Zhang, D., Meng, W., Li, X., Xu, F., 2011. A study of dea models without explicit inputs. Omega 39, 472–480.
- Pastor et al. (2022) Pastor, J.T., Aparicio, J., Zofío, J.L., 2022. Benchmarking Economic Efficiency: Technical and Allocative Fundamentals. International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, Springer Cham.
- Pastor et al. (1999) Pastor, J.T., Ruiz, J.L., Sirvent, I., 1999. An enhanced DEA Russell graph efficiency measure. European Journal of Operational Research 115, 596–607.
- Portela et al. (2004) Portela, M.C.A.S., Thanassoulis, E., Simpson, G., 2004. Negative data in DEA: A directional distance approach applied to bank branches. Journal of the Operational Research Society 55, 1111–1121. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jors.2601768.
- Ray (2008) Ray, S.C., 2008. The directional distance function and measurement of super-efficiency: an application to airlines data. Journal of the Operational Research Society 59, 788–797.
- Rockafellar (1970) Rockafellar, R.T., 1970. Convex analysis. Princeton Mathematical Series, No. 28, Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.
- Russell (1985) Russell, R.R., 1985. Measures of technical efficiency. Journal of Economic theory 35, 109–126.
- Russell and Schworm (2011) Russell, R.R., Schworm, W., 2011. Properties of inefficiency indexes on input, output space. Journal of Productivity Analysis 36, 143–156. doi:10.1007/s11123-011-0209-3.
- Russell and Schworm (2018) Russell, R.R., Schworm, W., 2018. Technological inefficiency indexes: A binary taxonomy and a generic theorem. Journal of Productivity Analysis 49, 17–23. doi:10.1007/s11123-017-0518-2.
- Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2007) Sueyoshi, T., Sekitani, K., 2007. Computational strategy for russell measure in dea: Second-order cone programming. European Journal of Operational Research 180, 459–471.
- Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2009) Sueyoshi, T., Sekitani, K., 2009. An occurrence of multiple projections in DEA-based measurement of technical efficiency: Theoretical comparison among DEA models from desirable properties. European Journal of Operational Research 196, 764–794. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2008.01.045.
- Talluri and Yoon (2000) Talluri, S., Yoon, K.P., 2000. A cone-ratio dea approach for amt justification. International Journal of Production Economics 66, 119–129.
- Toloo and Kresta (2014) Toloo, M., Kresta, A., 2014. Finding the best asset financing alternative: A dea–weo approach. Measurement 55, 288–294.
- Tone (2001) Tone, K., 2001. A slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. European Journal of Operational Research 130, 498–509.
- Tone et al. (2020) Tone, K., Chang, T.S., Wu, C.H., 2020. Handling negative data in slacks-based measure data envelopment analysis models. European Journal of Operational Research 282, 926–935.
- Xiong et al. (2019) Xiong, B., Chen, H., An, Q., Wu, J., 2019. A multi-objective distance friction minimization model for performance assessment through data envelopment analysis. European Journal of Operational Research 279, 132–142.