??? \publicationdate??? \articlenumber???
ODE models of wealth concentration and taxation
Abstract
We refer to an individual holding a non-negligible fraction of the country’s total wealth as an oligarch. We explain how a model due to Boghosian et al. [2] can be used to explore the effects of taxation on the emergence of oligarchs. The model suggests that oligarchs will emerge when wealth taxation is below a certain threshold, not when it is above the threshold. The underlying mechanism is a transcritical bifurcation. The model also suggests that taxation of income and capital gains alone cannot prevent the emergence of oligarchs. We suggest several opportunities for students to explore modifications of the model.
keywords:
wealth inequality, oligarchy, transcritical bifurcation1 Introduction
The concentration of wealth in the hands of a small number of individuals is considerable in many countries around the world, including the United States. In 2020, according to ref. [6], the 400 wealthiest Americans held 3.5% of the country’s total wealth. (The same article also estimated all Black households combined to hold a total of 3% of all U.S. wealth.) We present here a model extracted from Boghosian et al. [2], which sheds light on the effects of taxation on wealth concentration.
Individuals who hold a significant fraction of society’s total wealth, and therefore considerable political power [3], will be called oligarchs here. The model suggests the existence of a minimal rate of wealth taxation below which oligarchs may emerge. The underlying mathematical mechanism is a transcritical bifurcation [5].
We present and analyze the model in Section 2, discuss some variations in Section 3, and suggest problems for students to think about in Section 4. We very briefly sketch in Section 5 what is captured by the full model and analysis in [2], but is not reproduced in our discussion here.
2 Oligarchy and a flat wealth tax
We start by assuming that there are oligarchs holding a fraction of society’s wealth. We assume that in a short time , the oligarchs, by virtue of the power that their wealth gives them, acquire a small fraction of the wealth not yet in their hands:
(2.1) |
As increases, acquiring wealth becomes easier for the oligarchs: They can hire more lobbyists and better laywers, they can afford riskier but more profitable investments, and so on. It is therefore reasonable to assume that is proportional to , so
(2.2) |
You might think of as measuring the rate at which the oligarchs grab what’s not theirs yet; hence , the first letter in “grab”. We thereby arrive at the logistic growth equation
(2.3) |
Suppose now that the government taxes the oligarchs, taking away a small fraction of their wealth in time , where is another parameter. We use because it is the first letter in “rate” (of taxation). This is called a flat tax because does not dependent on . The equation now becomes
(2.4) |
Equation 2.4 has two fixed points, obtained by setting the right-hand side equal to zero and solving for :
(2.5) |
This is illustrated in Figure 1.

For , the fixed point is attracting, and is negative and repelling. In keeping with common convention, this is indicated by open circles and closed circles in Figure 1. For , the fixed point is positive and attracting, and is repelling. The interpretation is that for there will eventually be no oligarchs. For , there will be oligarchs (the attracting fixed point is positive). We have here an example of a transcritical bifurcation [5]. The two fixed points “collide” as moves through , and “exchange their stability properties”; see Figure 2.

The transcritical bifurcation that occurs as rises above can also be achieved by reducing below , that is, by reducing the wealth-acquired advantage — perhaps through public policy measures such as regulations on lobbying [1]. See Figure 3, and compare with [2, Figure 1].

In summary, the model suggests that taxing wealth sufficiently heavily can prevent oligarchy.
3 Variations
3.1 Flat income tax
To model the taxation of income (or capital gains), assume the government takes away a fixed fraction of the wealth gained by the oligarchs in time :
(3.1) |
If and , equation 3.1 has the attracting fixed point and the repelling fixed point . The model therefore suggests that income taxation alone does not prevent (total) oligarchy in the long run.
3.2 Progressive wealth tax
Progressive wealth taxation would mean that itself grows with . Assume , where is a fixed positive constant, and is a continuous,111We should assume that is Lipschitz continuous to remove any doubts regarding the existence and uniqueness of solutions of equation 3.2, but such technical points are not our focus here. monotonically increasing function of with . The equation now becomes
(3.2) |
Fixed points are obtained by setting the right-hand side equal to . One fixed point is always , corresponding to the absence of oligarchs. Other fixed points, if there are any, must solve
(3.3) |
To understand the solutions of equation 3.3 we plot the left-hand side as a function of , and, in the same plot, the right-hand side as well. Solutions of equation 3.3 are the abscissae of points where the two graphs meet. Examples are shown in Figure 4. If , there exists a positive fixed point and it is attracting, while the fixed point is repelling then. If , there exists a negative fixed point, but no positive one, and it is repelling, while the fixed point is attracting.

The conclusion is that a progressive wealth tax at rate yields the same threshold as a flat wealth tax at rate : Oligarchs emerge for , and not for . However, for , the positive fixed point will be smaller with a progressive wealth tax than it would be with a flat wealth tax at rate , so the oligarchs will hold less of society’s wealth; see Problem 4.3.
4 Suggested problems
Problem 4.1.
Modified model of the wealth-acquired advantage. Equation 2.2 seems a bit arbitrary. While it seems plausible that should be an increasing function of , why should it be proportional to ? What happens if for instance? Then equation 2.4 is replaced by
Determine the fixed points of this equation, study the bifurcation that occurs as is raised or is lowered, and interpret the results in terms of the emergence or absence of oligarchs. Try other modifications that make sense to you as well.
Problem 4.2.
Progressive income tax. Suppose that the fraction of the oligarchs’ gains taken away by the government is not a fixed , but rather
where is a monotonically increasing function of with . The greater the oligarchs’ gain in a unit of time, the greater a percentage of their gains will be taken away from them. You may want to assume that the government will never take away as much as 100% of the oligarchs’ gains.222The Swedish children’s book author Astrid Lindgren complained in 1976 that her marginal tax rate had risen to 102%. She wrote a satirical story about it, published in the Swedish tabloid Expressen [4]. It should be said that there is a distinction between the marginal tax rate — the rate at which the last dollar of income is taxed — and the effective one. Lindgren, by the way, supported the Swedish Social Democrats, who had introduced those steeply progressive income tax rates, throughout her life, even after 1976., so for all . Now the equation is
Will oligarchs be able to persist?
Problem 4.3.
Progressive wealth tax re-visited. Assume a progressive wealth tax with . Explain why the positive fixed point of equation 2.4 is closer to zero than it would be with a flat wealth tax at rate .
Problem 4.4.
Regressive wealth tax. Suppose that as increases, the oligarchs, by virtue of their increasing political power, manage to reduce the wealth tax rate. So the equation is 3.2, but now is a decreasing function of with and . Analyze what happens. (It will depend on what you assume about the function .)
5 What the full model is about
We mentioned that the model suggested here is extracted from a model due to Boghosian et al. [2]. What would you learn by reading [2] that you cannot learn here? The essential answer is that you would learn about the distribution of wealth, not merely about the fraction of wealth held by the oligarchs. As a result, the model of [2] predicts things like the Lorenz curve and the Gini coefficient. Our equation 2.4, supported here by plausibility arguments only, is derived in [2] (see equation 17 in [2]) from a model of the time evolution of the wealth distribution.
References
- Baumgartner et al. [2009] F. R. Baumgartner, J. M. Berry, M. Hojnaicki, D. C. Kimball, and B. L. Leech. Lobbying and Policy Change. The University of Chicago Press, 2009.
- Boghosian et al. [2016] B. Boghosian, A. Devitt-Lee, and H. Wang. The growth of oligarchy in a yard-sale model of asset exchange – a logistic equation for wealth condensation. Proc. 1st Int. Conf. Complex Inf. Syst., pages 187–193, 2016.
- Krugman [July 1, 2020] P. Krugman. Why do the rich have so much power? New York Times, July 1, 2020.
- Lindgren [March 3, 1976] A. Lindgren. Pomperipossa in Monismania, translation of the original Swedish into English by Lennart Bilén, 2009. Expressen, March 3, 1976.
- Strogatz [2015] S. H. Strogatz. Nonlinear Dynamics and Chaos. Westview Press, 2nd edition, 2015.
- Williamson [2020] V. Williamson. Closing the racial wealth gap requires heavy, progressive taxation of wealth. Brookings Institution, 2020.
Sketches of solutions for the problems
The problems are intended to inspire the reader to investigate on their own, and the solution sketches given here are not meant to undermine that, but to assist a reader who would like help getting started.
4.1. Modified model of the wealth-acquired advantage. For the modified equation, is still a fixed point. Since the linearization of around is , the fixed point is always attracting now. Other fixed points must satisfy
Plot as a function of to see that there are no solutions of this equation when , and there are two solutions, both strictly between and , when . The larger of the two positive fixed points is then attracting, and the smaller is repelling. If is perturbed from slightly, it returns to the attracting fixed point , but if is raised beyond the smaller positive fixed point, which acts as a threshold, it converges to the larger one. This is an example of an excitable system [5]. The bifurcation that annihilates the two positive fixed points as rises above is a saddle-node bifurcation [5].
Now think about other possible relations between and .
4.2. Progressive income tax. If for all , the only two fixed points are still and , and is repelling, is attracting. But what if we allow ?
4.3. Progressive wealth tax re-visited. Ask yourself what Figure 4 would look like if the wealth tax were flat.
4.4 Regressive wealth tax. The simplest example would be . Equation 3.2 then becomes
This equation has fixed points at and . For , the fixed point at is repelling, and that at 1 is attracting. For , the fixed point at is attracting, and that at 1 is repelling. So even the regressive wealth tax with still leads to the conclusion that oligarchy emerges if , but not if .
If you were to make plots like those in Figures 2 and 3 (with replacing ), what would they look like now? Is it still a transcritical bifurcation?
Next think about other examples, for instance ; that would mean that the oligarchs become really effective at fighting the wealth tax only when they have acquired enough wealth.