This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

Modeling the impact of birth control policies on China’s population and age: effects of delayed births and minimum birth age constraints

Yue Wang Renaud Dessalles Tom Chou
Abstract

We consider age-structured models with an imposed refractory period between births. These models can be used to formulate alternative population control strategies to China’s one-child policy. By allowing any number of births, but with an imposed delay between births, we show how the total population can be decreased and how a relatively older age distribution can be generated. This delay represents a more “continuous” form of population management for which the strict one-child policy is a limiting case. Such a policy approach could be more easily accepted by society. Our analyses provide an initial framework for studying demographics and how social constraints influence population structure.

Keywords: population biology, demographics, McKendrick equation, population control, one-child policy

1 Introduction

Models of age-structured population dynamics are often based on the classic McKendrick equation (McKendrick, 1926; Kermack and McKendrick, 1927) (sometimes called von Foerster equation (von Foerster, 1959)). These equations describe the dynamics of the mean population as a function of time tt and expressed as a density in age aa. The solutions to the McKendrick equations can be partially solved using the method of characteristics and numerical approximations (Perthame, 2007; Keyfitz and Keyfitz, 1997) across many contexts. Moreover, stochastic extensions to incorporate the random times of birth and death (demographic stochasticity) have been formulated using branching processes (Jiang et al., 2017) and kinetic and operator theory (Greenman and Chou, 2016; Chou and Greenman, 2016; Greenman, 2017; Xia and Chou, 2021)

Age-structured equations have been used to predict the evolution of human and animal populations (Tuljapurkar, 1983; Bongaarts and Greenhalgh, 1985; Feeney and Yu, 1987). Using such models and ideas from control theory to frame population control strategies was vogue in the 1970s (Langhaar, 1972; Pollard, 1973; Falkenburg, 1973; Hritonenko and Yatsenko, 2010). A profound example was its use in 1979 by Jian Song (Song, 1980, 1982), a Chinese engineer who numerically solved the one-component McKendrick equation using birth rates associated with China in the late 1970s (see Fig. 1). By projecting future populations associated with different birth rates (expressed by the mean number of children per woman), he found that in order to keep the population manageable (\sim 700 million - 1 billion) within 100 years, this control parameter would have to be decreased to the point where each woman is allowed only one child (Song, 1980, 1982; Song et al., 1988). This research provided the technical basis of the one-child policy in China (Greenhalgh, 2004; Bacaër, 2011).

In the 1970s, China had encouraged (but not enforced) people to marry later, wait longer before childbearing, and have fewer children (“later-longer-fewer” policy) (Bongaarts and Greenhalgh, 1985). Despite concerns from social scientists and demographers who proposed such “softer” controls, the one-child policy was implemented in 1980, based on the implications of Jian Song’s numerical solutions to the McKendrick equation. Rather than imposing a maximal number of children, a minimum delay between two consecutive births (Greenhalgh, 2004) or a minimum birth age could have been imposed. Such a policy would arguably have been more easily enforced and would have led to fewer unintended consequences such as a skewed sex ratio and an elder-heavy age distribution. Here, we retrospectively model such alternatives and make predictions as policies change.

Specifically, we extend the McKendrick age-structured model to incorporate a delay between successive births by each female. In order to do so, we must explicitly delineate individuals who have not given birth from those who have given birth at least once. Imposed delays between successive births can then be formally described by adjusting the birth rate function of the individuals who have given birth at least once. We solve our model equations using parameters appropriate to 1981 China and compare predictions of the graded policies with those of a strict one-child policy. We explore how the total population and age distribution are affected by different values of imposed refractory periods and minimum birth age.

2 Mathematical Model

When applying age-structured partial differential equation (PDE) models to two-sex populations, a simple assumption is to consider only the density of females at time tt with age aa. The predicted number of females with age between aa and a+daa+\textrm{d}a is thus f(a,t)daf(a,t)\textrm{d}a. Indeed, unless the female population is much larger than the male population (e.g., after a war), the female population can be considered as the “limiting quantity” that determines the number of births. In other words, the frequency of births in the total population is relatively insensitive to the male population. The McKendrick equations describing the female population density f(a,t)f(a,t) are formulated as

tf(t,a)+af(t,a)=μf(a)f(t,a)\displaystyle\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f(t,a)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f(t,a)=-\mu_{\rm f}(a)f(t,a) (1a)
f(t,0)=η0βeff(a)f(t,a)da\displaystyle f(t,0)=\eta\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\beta_{\text{eff}}(a)f(t,a)\textrm{d}a (1b)
f(0,a)=If(a),\displaystyle f(0,a)=I_{\rm f}(a), (1c)

where μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) represents the death rate of females of age aa, βeff(a)\beta_{\text{eff}}(a) is the observed birth rate of women of age aa, η\eta is the fraction of births that produce girls, and If(a)I_{\rm f}(a) is the age distribution of the initial population at t=0t=0.

Equation (1a) describes the time-evolution of the population, Eq. (1b) denotes the boundary condition at age a=0a=0 describing the number of girls born at time tt, and Eq. (1c) specifies the initial condition. This model neglects the explicit mating-age male population which is valid when η\eta is maintained below 0.50.5, giving rise to more males than females. For humans, η0.480.49\eta\approx 0.48-0.49 naturally (but this is compensated by a slightly higher mortality in males across all ages). With sex-selective abortion, η\eta can be even smaller (Li and Meng, 2014). If one were also interested in the male population m(t,a)m(t,a), it would obey the same equations except with a male version of the death rate μm(a)\mu_{\rm m}(a), an initial condition Im(a)I_{\rm m}(a), and a boundary condition for male newborns: m(t,0)=(1η)0βeff(a)f(t,a)dam(t,0)=(1-\eta)\int_{0}^{\infty}\beta_{\rm eff}(a)f(t,a)\textrm{d}a.

2.1 Delayed birth model

Now, in order to introduce a delay between consecutive births, we need to further partition the female population into those who have never had a child and those who have already had a child (and who may need to wait a certain time before having another one). The population densities for each of these classes of females are defined as:

f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a):

the population density of childless females. The quantity f0(t,a)daf_{0}(t,a)\textrm{d}a is the number of females with age between aa and a+daa+\textrm{d}a and who have never had a child up to the current time tt.

f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau):

the population of females who have had at least one child. The quantity f(t,a,τ)dadτf(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}a\textrm{d}\tau is the number of females at time tt whose age is between aa and a+daa+\textrm{d}a and whose youngest child’s age is between τ\tau and τ+dτ\tau+\textrm{d}\tau.

We will assume that these two populations have the same age-dependent death rate μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) but give birth at different rates β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) and β(a,τ)\beta(a,\tau), respectively. We also define the total female population density as

ftot(t,a)=f0(t,a)+0af(t,a,τ)dτf_{\rm tot}(t,a)=f_{0}(t,a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau (2)

and the total number of females at time tt as

n(t)=0ftot(t,a)da=0f0(t,a)da+0da0adτf(t,a,τ).n(t)=\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!f_{\rm tot}(t,a)\textrm{d}a=\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!f_{0}(t,a)\textrm{d}a+\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\textrm{d}a\int_{0}^{a}\!\!\textrm{d}\tau f(t,a,\tau). (3)

The age-structured McKendrick equations for f0f_{0} and ff are:

tf0(t,a)+af0(t,a)\displaystyle\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f_{0}(t,a)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f_{0}(t,a) =(μf(a)+β0(a))f0(t,a)\displaystyle={}-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta_{0}(a)\right)f_{0}(t,a) (4a)
tf(t,a,τ)+af(t,a,τ)+τf(t,a,τ)\displaystyle\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f(t,a,\tau)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f(t,a,\tau)+\frac{\partial}{\partial\tau}f(t,a,\tau) =(μf(a)+β(a,τ))f(t,a,τ)\displaystyle={}-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta(a,\tau)\right)f(t,a,\tau) (4b)
f0(t,0)\displaystyle f_{0}(t,0) =η(0β0(a)f0(t,a)da+0da0adτβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ))\displaystyle=\eta\left(\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\beta_{0}(a)f_{0}(t,a)\textrm{d}a+\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\textrm{d}a\int_{0}^{a}\!\!\textrm{d}\tau\,\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\right) (4c)
f(t,a,0)\displaystyle f(t,a,0) =β0(a)f0(t,a)+0aβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ)dτ\displaystyle=\beta_{0}(a)f_{0}(t,a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!\!\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau (4d)
f0(0,a)\displaystyle f_{0}(0,a) =I0(a)andf(0,a,τ)=I(a,τ).\displaystyle=I_{0}(a)\quad\text{and}\quad f(0,a,\tau)=I(a,\tau). (4e)

Equation (4a) describes the evolution of f0f_{0} as in the classical McKendrick equation (cf Eq. (1a)) with birth rate β0(a)\beta_{0}(a). For f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau), we must introduce the new variable τ\tau to mark the time since the last birth. This brings in another convection term in Eq. (4b) since τ\tau increases alongside time tt and age aa. The birth rate β\beta for this population can depend on both the age aa and the time τ\tau since the last birth. Eq. (4c) gives the number of girls f0(t,0)f_{0}(t,0) born at time tt, while Eq. (4d) describes f(t,a,0)f(t,a,0), the density of females at age aa at time tt who just gave birth. These individuals can arise from the f0f_{0} population (females who have never had a child) or from the ff population itself (females who have already had at least one child). Thus, the boundary conditions  (4c) and  (4d) couple the two populations f0f_{0} and ff. Finally, equations (4e) simply describe the initial conditions for f0f_{0} and ff.

In Appendix A, we explicitly show that the total female population density ftot(t,a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a) (Eq. (2)) satisfies the standard age-structured McKendrick equation

tftot(t,a)+aftot(t,a)=μf(a)ftot(t,a).\begin{split}\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f_{\rm tot}(t,a)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f_{\rm tot}(t,a)=-\mu_{\rm f}(a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a).\end{split} (5)

Within a model that explicitly considers the time τ\tau since the last childbirth, we can easily describe an imposed hypothetical policy that applies a refractory period δ\delta between births. After having a child and before this refractory period (0τδ0\leq\tau\leq\delta) expires, the birth rate β(a,τ)\beta(a,\tau) can be set to 0. As a preliminary description, we will consider a policy-modified (truncated) birth rate function

β(a,τ)=β0(a)𝟙(τ,δ)\beta(a,\tau)=\beta_{0}(a)\mathds{1}(\tau,\delta) (6)

where the indicator function 𝟙(τ,δ)=1\mathds{1}(\tau,\delta)=1 for τ>δ\tau>\delta and 𝟙(τ,δ)=0\mathds{1}(\tau,\delta)=0 for τδ\tau\leq\delta. This form assumes that once the imposed refractory period has past, the birth rate immediately rises back to a value associated with the persons current age.

2.2 Asymptotic behavior

We first analyze the asymptotic behavior of our model. An important feature of renewal transport equations such as the McKendrick model is that as tt\to\infty, the total population n(t)n(t) will grow exponentially (in the absence of nonlinear regulation terms (Gurtin and MacCamy, 1974)), while the normalized, age-dependent population density converges to a time-independent stationary distribution (see Perthame (2007, Chapter 3) and Arino (1995)). This property is independent of the initial condition. We will assume that this steady-state asymptotic property arises in our two-component, three-variable model; i.e., the normalized densities f0(t,a)/n(t)f_{0}(t,a)/n(t) and f(t,a,τ)/n(t)f(t,a,\tau)/n(t) converge to stationary distributions. We denote the stationary limits as

limtf0(t,a)n(t)h0(a)andlimtf(t,a,τ)n(t)h(a,τ).\lim_{t\to\infty}\frac{f_{0}(t,a)}{n(t)}\equiv h_{0}(a)\quad\text{and}\quad\lim_{t\to\infty}\frac{f(t,a,\tau)}{n(t)}\equiv h(a,\tau). (7)

We also define the distribution associated with the total female population as

limtftot(t,a)n(t)htot(a)=h0(a)+0ah(a,τ)dτ,\lim_{t\to\infty}\frac{f_{\rm tot}(t,a)}{n(t)}\equiv h_{\rm tot}(a)=h_{0}(a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau, (8)

where 0htot(a)da=1\int_{0}^{\infty}h_{\rm tot}(a)\textrm{d}a=1. If we assume that f0(0,a)/n(0)=h0(a)f_{0}(0,a)/n(0)=h_{0}(a) and f(0,a,τ)/n(0)=h(a,τ)f(0,a,\tau)/n(0)=h(a,\tau) for any a,τa,\tau at some initial time t=0t=0, then f0(t,a)/n(t)=h0(a)f_{0}(t,a)/n(t)=h_{0}(a) and f(t,a,τ)/n(t)=h(a,τ)f(t,a,\tau)/n(t)=h(a,\tau) hold for any t0t\geq 0.

From Eq. (4a), we have

1f0(t,a)f0(t,a)t\displaystyle\frac{1}{f_{0}(t,a)}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a)}{\partial t} =1f0(t,a)f0(t,a)aμf(a)\displaystyle=-\frac{1}{f_{0}(t,a)}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a)}{\partial a}-\mu_{\rm f}(a) (9)
=n(t)f0(t,a)1n(t)f0(t,a)aμf(a)\displaystyle=-\frac{n(t)}{f_{0}(t,a)}\frac{1}{n(t)}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a)}{\partial a}-\mu_{\rm f}(a)
=1h0(a)dh0(a)daμf(a).\displaystyle=\frac{1}{h_{0}(a)}\frac{\textrm{d}h_{0}(a)}{\textrm{d}a}-\mu_{\rm f}(a).

Thus, [f0(t,a)/t]/f0(t,a)[\partial f_{0}(t,a)/\partial t]/f_{0}(t,a) is independent of tt. Moreover, for any a,a,τa,a^{\prime},\tau

f0(t,a)f(t,a,τ)=h0(a)n(t)n(t)h(a,τ)=h0(a)h(a,τ)\frac{f_{0}(t,a)}{f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)}=\frac{h_{0}(a)}{n(t)}\frac{n(t)}{h(a^{\prime},\tau)}=\frac{h_{0}(a)}{h(a^{\prime},\tau)} (10)

is also independent of tt so that

t[f0(t,a)f(t,a,τ)]=1f(t,a,τ)2[f(t,a,τ)tf0(t,a)f0(t,a)tf(t,a,τ)]=0.\frac{\partial}{\partial t}\left[\frac{f_{0}(t,a)}{f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)}\right]=\frac{1}{f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)^{2}}\left[f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f_{0}(t,a)-f_{0}(t,a)\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)\right]=0. (11)

Thus, for any a,a,τa,a^{\prime},\tau,

1f0(t,a)f0(t,a)t=1f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,τ)t=1f0(t,a)f0(t,a)t.\frac{1}{f_{0}(t,a)}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a)}{\partial t}=\frac{1}{f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)}\frac{\partial f(t,a^{\prime},\tau)}{\partial t}=\frac{1}{f_{0}(t,a^{\prime})}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a^{\prime})}{\partial t}. (12)

Eqs. (9) and (12) show that [f0(t,a)/t]/f0(t,a)[\partial f_{0}(t,a)/\partial t]/f_{0}(t,a) is independent of both tt and aa, allowing us to define a constant that describes the stationary growth rate

λ=1f0(t,a)f0(t,a)t=1f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,τ)t=1ftot(t,a)ftot(t,a)t.\lambda=\frac{1}{f_{0}(t,a)}\frac{\partial f_{0}(t,a)}{\partial t}=\frac{1}{f(t,a,\tau)}\frac{\partial f(t,a,\tau)}{\partial t}=\frac{1}{f_{\rm tot}(t,a)}\frac{\partial f_{\rm tot}(t,a)}{\partial t}. (13)

Thus, we can express solutions for the densities f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a) and f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau) in the form

f0(t,a)=Ch0(a)eλtandf(t,a,τ)=Ch(a,τ)eλt,f_{0}(t,a)=Ch_{0}(a)e^{\lambda t}\quad\text{and}\quad f(t,a,\tau)=Ch(a,\tau)e^{\lambda t}, (14)

where CC is a constant. After using these expressions in Eqs. (4), we find the equations for the stationary distributions

ddah0(a)\displaystyle\frac{\textrm{d}}{\textrm{d}a}h_{0}(a) =(μf(a)+β0(a)+λ)h0(a)\displaystyle=-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta_{0}(a)+\lambda\right)h_{0}(a) (15a)
ah(a,τ)+τh(a,τ)\displaystyle\frac{\partial}{\partial a}h(a,\tau)+\frac{\partial}{\partial\tau}h(a,\tau) =(μf(a)+β(a,τ)+λ)h(a,τ)\displaystyle=-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta(a,\tau)+\lambda\right)h(a,\tau) (15b)
h0(0)\displaystyle h_{0}(0) =η(0β0(a)h0(a)da+0da0adτβ(a,τ)h(a,τ))\displaystyle=\eta\left(\int_{0}^{\infty}\beta_{0}(a)h_{0}(a)\textrm{d}a+\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\textrm{d}a\int_{0}^{a}\!\textrm{d}\tau\,\beta(a,\tau)h(a,\tau)\right) (15c)
h(a,0)\displaystyle h(a,0) =β0(a)h0(a)+0aβ(a,τ)h(a,τ)dτ.\displaystyle=\beta_{0}(a)h_{0}(a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!\beta(a,\tau)h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau. (15d)

Next, using Eq. (5), we find

ddahtot(a)=(μf(a)+λ)htot(a),\frac{\textrm{d}}{\textrm{d}a}h_{\rm tot}(a)=-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\lambda\right)h_{\rm tot}(a), (16)

which is solved by

htot(a)=htot(0)exp[aλ0aμf(a)da].h_{\rm tot}(a)=h_{\rm tot}(0)\exp\left[-a\lambda-\int_{0}^{a}\!\!\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]. (17)

We can then define the effective whole-population birth rate function

βeff(a)=β0(a)h0(a)+0aβ(a,τ)h(a,τ)dτhtot(a),\beta_{\rm eff}(a)=\frac{\beta_{0}(a)h_{0}(a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!\beta(a,\tau)h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}{h_{\rm tot}(a)}, (18)

which describes the overall birthrate weighted over the entire stationary population. This population-averaged birth rate βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) corresponds to that used in the basic lumped model (Eq. (1b)) and is the quantity that can be directly extracted from birth data that provide women’s ages at time of birth, but that may not distinguish whether females are first-time mothers. We prove in Appendix B that given βeff(a)\beta_{\text{eff}}(a), the new-mother birth rate function can be calculated from

β0(a)=βeff(a)10δβeff(aτ)dτ,\beta_{0}(a)=\frac{\beta_{\text{eff}}(a)}{1-\int_{0}^{\delta}\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}, (19)

which then allows us to reconstruct β(a,τ)\beta(a,\tau) from Eq. (6). Using βeff\beta_{\rm eff}, the boundary condition for Eq. (16), the counterpart to Eq. (15c), can be written as

htot(0)=η0βeff(a)htot(a)da.h_{\rm tot}(0)=\eta\int_{0}^{\infty}\beta_{\rm eff}(a)h_{\rm tot}(a)\textrm{d}a. (20)

Finally, after using the solution in Eq. 17 for htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a) in Eq. (20), we find an equation for λ\lambda:

z(λ)η0βeff(a)exp[aλ0aμf(a)da]da=1.z(\lambda)\equiv\eta\int_{0}^{\infty}\beta_{\rm eff}(a)\exp\left[-a\lambda-\int_{0}^{a}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]\textrm{d}a=1. (21)

The function z(λ)z(\lambda) is monotonically decreasing with λ\lambda and obeys the limits limλ+z(λ)=0\lim_{\lambda\to+\infty}z(\lambda)=0 and limλz(λ)=+\lim_{\lambda\to-\infty}z(\lambda)=+\infty. Thus, Eq. (21) has a unique solution that can easily be found numerically. From Eq. (21), the solution for λ\lambda–the net population growth rate–clearly increases with βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) and decreases with μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a).

With β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) and λ\lambda determined by Eqs.  (19) and (21), respectively, we can explicitly find h(a,τ)h(a,\tau). First, we use the normalization condition 0htot(a)da=1\int_{0}^{\infty}h_{\rm tot}(a)\textrm{d}a=1 on Eq. (16) to explicitly find htot(0)h_{\rm tot}(0) in terms of λ\lambda and μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a). Since h(0,τ)=0h(0,\tau)=0, we have h0(0)=htot(0)h_{0}(0)=h_{\rm tot}(0), which allows us to explicitly express the solution to Eq. (15a):

h0(a)=h0(0)exp[aλ0a(μf(a)+β0(a))da].h_{0}(a)=h_{0}(0)\exp\left[-a\lambda-\int_{0}^{a}\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta_{0}(a^{\prime})\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]. (22)

Next, we use Eq. (15d) and Eq. (18) to eliminate β(a,τ)\beta(a,\tau) and find h(a,0)=htot(a)βeff(a)h(a,0)=h_{\rm tot}(a)\beta_{\text{eff}}(a), which is known. Thus, we can explicitly calculate h(a,τ)h(a,\tau) by solving Eq. (15b) using the method of characteristics:

h(a,τ)=h(aτ,0)exp[τλaτa(μf(a)+β(a,aa+τ))da].h(a,\tau)=h(a-\tau,0)\exp\left[-\tau\lambda-\int_{a-\tau}^{a}\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta(a^{\prime},a^{\prime}-a+\tau)\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]. (23)

To summarize, starting from βeff(a),μf(a),η\beta_{\text{eff}}(a),\mu_{\rm f}(a),\eta (measured, say), and δ\delta, we can compute the growth rate λ\lambda numerically, then analytically reconstruct β0(a),β(a,τ),h0(a)\beta_{0}(a),\beta(a,\tau),h_{0}(a) and h(a,τ)h(a,\tau).

Refer to caption
Figure 1: China’s 1981 birth rate and female death rate μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a), calculated from 1982 national census data (Population Census Office under the State Council, 1985). The red curve represents the observed birth rate βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) for all women of a given age. The dashed blue curve represents the birth rate β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) for females who have not had any children. The area under the observed birth rate 0βeff(a)da\int_{0}^{\infty}\!\!\beta_{\rm eff}(a)\textrm{d}a represents the mean number of children born during over an individual’s lifetime.

We now use the Chinese national census data recorded in 1982 (Population Census Office under the State Council, 1985) to infer the overall birth rate βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) and the female death rate μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) functions in China in 1981. Although gestation imposes a hard refractory period of δ9\delta\approx 9 months, some time is needed to recover from childbirth and the birth rate should more gradually recover. Specifically, in 1981 China, extended breastfeeding was common, which prevents the next pregnancy (Xu et al., 2009). Thus, we will assume the birth rate returns to normal approximately only after about two years. Therefore, when there is no policy that controls the interval between births, we set δ=2\delta=2 years such that β(a,τ)=0\beta(a,\tau)=0 for τ<2\tau<2 years and β(a,τ)=β0(a)\beta(a,\tau)=\beta_{0}(a) for τ>2\tau>2 years. For other societies, this natural refractory period might be shorter. Using δ=2\delta=2 and Eq. (19), we calculate β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) from βeff(a)\beta_{\text{eff}}(a) derived from data. These rates are illustrated in Fig. 1. Note that β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) for 1981 has already been mildly affected by the incipient birth-control policies in China.

Using the birth rate βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) and death rate μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) shown in Fig.  1, we solve Eqs. (15) to find h0(a)h_{0}(a) and h(a,τ)h(a,\tau), and plot them with htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a) given by Eq. (17) in Fig. 2(a,b).

Refer to caption
Figure 2: The asymptotic population distribution associated with the birth and death rates shown in Fig. 1. (a) Steady-state age distributions of females without children, h0(a)h_{0}(a), and all females, htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a), respectively. A monotonically decreasing htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a) indicates that there are larger numbers of younger females, consistent with an increasing population and λ>0\lambda>0. (b) The full double density h(a,τ)h(a,\tau) of females of age aa and whose youngest child is τ\tau years old.

To explore the effects of an imposed refractory period, we first set δ=2\delta=2 years, apply the newborn sex ratio of China in 1981, η=0.48\eta=0.48, and solve Eq. (21). We find λ0.005>0\lambda\simeq 0.005>0, indicating an exponentially growing total population. This stationary growth rate is much smaller than the actual growth rate of China in 1981, which is 0.0146. One reason is that in 1981, the proportion of younger females is much higher than that in the stationary distribution htoth_{\rm tot}. The shape of htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a) is consistent with this growth as it is monotonically decreasing, indicating that every new generation has a larger population than the previous one. In Fig. 3, we see how increases in the refractory period δ\delta decrease the asymptotic growth rate λ\lambda and affect the distribution htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a). A negative overall birth rate λ<0\lambda<0 (i.e., an asymptotically decaying population) arises when δ3.22\delta\gtrsim 3.22 years 39\approx 39 months. As soon as λ<0\lambda<0, the distribution htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a) becomes nonmonotonic, and a peak in the female population distribution arises at a finite age a>0a>0.

If δ\delta is set sufficiently large, a female cannot have a second child, and the outcome is equivalent to a strict one-child policy. We use the terminology “strict one-child policy” for the scenario in which each female can have strictly no more than one child, while we use “one-child policy” to refer to the actual policy realized in practice. From 1980 to 1990, the one-child policy contained many exceptions, allowing one to bear more than one child (Nie, 1999).

Refer to caption
Figure 3: Asymptotic total-population growth rate and the steady-state, total-population age distribution. (a) Effect of an imposed interbirth delay δ\delta on the asymptotic growth rate λ\lambda. Most of the decrease in λ\lambda occurs at small values of δ\delta where the most negative slopes arise. When δ\delta is large enough, a woman ages out before giving birth again, and imposing interbirth delay is equivalent to the strict one-child policy. (b) The steady-state age distribution htot(a)h_{\rm tot}(a). As δ\delta increases, the peak of population density moves from 0 to approximately 6565.

Our formulation is valid only in the asymptotic case with a fixed delay δ\delta that remains unchanged for a long period of time. For practical modeling of policies in which delays δ\delta are used as a time-dependent control variable, such as China’s 1980 one-child policy and its subsequent modification in 2015, it is necessary to analyze the full model that delineates the two female populations.

2.3 Temporal evolution

As was used to predict the effects of the one-child policy, we use China’s female age distribution in 1981 (Population Census Office under the State Council, 1985) as a starting point to explore how the total population evolves under different values of the imposed delay δ\delta. Since the data only contain total female numbers Itot(a)I_{\rm tot}(a) and not I0(a)I_{0}(a) and I(a,τ)I(a,\tau) individually, we use I0(a)=Itot(a)h0(a)/htot(a)I_{0}(a)=I_{\rm tot}(a)h_{0}(a)/h_{\rm tot}(a) and I(a,τ)=Itot(a)h(a,τ)/htot(a)I(a,\tau)=I_{\rm tot}(a)h(a,\tau)/h_{\rm tot}(a) to reconstruct these initial age distributions. These initial distributions are plotted in Fig. 4(a). With these initial conditions, we can solve Eq. (4a) and Eq. (4b) with the method of characteristics to find the full age and time dependence of the female populations

f0(t,a)\displaystyle f_{0}(t,a) =f0(ta,0)exp[0a(μf(a)+β0(a))da]if t>a\displaystyle=f_{0}(t-a,0)\exp\left[-\int_{0}^{a}\!\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta_{0}(a^{\prime})\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]\ \text{if }t>a (24a)
f0(t,a)\displaystyle f_{0}(t,a) =I0(at)exp[ata(μf(a)+β0(a))da]if ta,\displaystyle=I_{0}(a-t)\exp\left[-\int_{a-t}^{a}\!\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta_{0}(a^{\prime})\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]\ \ \ \text{if }t\leq a, (24b)
f(t,a,τ)\displaystyle f(t,a,\tau) =f(tτ,aτ,0)exp[aτa(μf(a)+β(a,a(aτ)))da]if t>τ\displaystyle=f(t-\tau,a-\tau,0)\exp\left[-\int_{a-\tau}^{a}\!\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta\left(a^{\prime},a^{\prime}-(a-\tau)\right)\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]\ \text{if }t>\tau (25a)
f(t,a,τ)\displaystyle f(t,a,\tau) =I(at,τt)exp[ata(μf(a)+β(a,a(aτ)))da]if tτ.\displaystyle=I(a-t,\tau-t)\exp\left[-\int_{a-t}^{a}\!\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})+\beta\left(a^{\prime},a^{\prime}-(a-\tau)\right)\big{)}\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]\ \ \ \ \ \ \text{if }t\leq\tau. (25b)

Females are fertile only between sexual maturity and menopause. Thus, we set amina_{\min} (12\sim 12 years) and amaxa_{\max} (50\sim 50 years), so that β0(a)=β(a,τ)=0\beta_{0}(a)=\beta(a,\tau)=0 for a<amina<a_{\min} or a>amaxa>a_{\max}. Recall that an imposed policy delayed-birth policy is manifested by β(a,τ)=0\beta(a,\tau)=0 for τ<δ\tau<\delta. Eq. (4c) becomes

f0(t,0)=η(aminamaxβ0(a)f0(t,a)da+aminamaxdaδadτβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ)).f_{0}(t,0)=\eta\left(\int_{a_{\min}}^{a_{\max}}\!\!\beta_{0}(a)f_{0}(t,a)\textrm{d}a+\int_{a_{\min}}^{a_{\max}}\!\!\!\textrm{d}a\int_{\delta}^{a}\!\!\textrm{d}\tau\,\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\right). (26)

For tγmin{amin,δ}t\leq\gamma\equiv\min\{a_{\min},\delta\}, the f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a) and f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau) terms in the integrands in Eq. (26) can be solved by Eq. (24b) and Eq. (25b). Thus, we can express f0(t,0)f_{0}(t,0) in terms of I0(a),I(a,τ),β0(a),β(a,τ)I_{0}(a),I(a,\tau),\beta_{0}(a),\beta(a,\tau), and μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a). Using Eqs. (24), we can calculate f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a) for any aa and tγt\leq\gamma. Under the imposed refractory period, Eq. (4d) becomes

f(t,a,0)=f0(t,a)β0(a)+δaβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ)dτ.f(t,a,0)=f_{0}(t,a)\beta_{0}(a)+\int_{\delta}^{a}\!\!\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau. (27)

If tγt\leq\gamma, we can also use Eq. (25b) for f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau) in the integrand of Eq. (27), and then use the solved f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a) to express f(t,a,0)f(t,a,0) in terms of I0(a),I(a,τ),β0(a),β(a,τ)I_{0}(a),I(a,\tau),\beta_{0}(a),\beta(a,\tau), and μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a). Using Eqs. (25), we can calculate f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau) for any a,τa,\tau and tγt\leq\gamma. Finally, using f0(γ,a),f(γ,a,τ)f_{0}(\gamma,a),f(\gamma,a,\tau) as the initial conditions, we can solve f0(t,a),f(t,a,τ)f_{0}(t,a),f(t,a,\tau) for t2γt\leq 2\gamma. Repeating this procedure, we can use I0(a),I(a,τ),β0(a),β(a,τ)I_{0}(a),I(a,\tau),\beta_{0}(a),\beta(a,\tau), and μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) to calculate f0(t,a)f_{0}(t,a) and f(t,a,τ)f(t,a,\tau) for any t,a,τt,a,\tau.

Using the fundamental rates β0(a)\beta_{0}(a), μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) and β(a,τ)\beta(a,\tau) as those used in the previous subsection for the full model (see Fig. 1 and Eq. (6)), we use the above procedure to construct the total female population n(t)n(t) (see Eq. 3). The evolution of n(t)n(t) over one century, under different interbirth delays, are plotted in Fig. 4(b). At long times, the total population exhibits the asymptotic behavior predicted by the eigenvalues shown in Fig. 3(a). For δ3.22\delta\gtrsim 3.22 years, the total population will decrease exponentially. Because the total population growth rate is most sensitive to small values of imposed delay δ\delta, even a delay of δ4\delta\sim 4 years is sufficient to dramatically reduce population over the next 100100 year, compared to the δ=2\delta=2 case of no refractory period.

The formal results and analyses above can be generalized to include time dependent parameters μf(t,a)\mu_{\rm f}(t,a), β0(t,a)\beta_{0}(t,a), β(t,a,τ)\beta(t,a,\tau), and even δ(t)\delta(t) to reflect social and policy changes. In this case, am imposed refractory period would be defined by the time-dependent birth rate function β(t,a,τ)=β0(t,a)𝟙(τ>δ(t))\beta(t,a,\tau)=\beta_{0}(t,a)\mathds{1}(\tau>\delta(t)) and the population densities will need to be evaluated numerically.

Refer to caption
Figure 4: Evolution of the population for different delays. (a) Initial female subpopulation distributions in 1981 China (calculated from Population Census Office under the State Council (1985)). (b) Evolution of the total female population n(t)n(t) for different imposed delays between births. These results are determined using the birth and death rates in Fig. 1 and the initial populations shown in (a). A relatively small delay between births (for example, δ4\delta\sim 4 years) has a significant impact on the evolution of n(t)n(t).

3 Results and Discussion

Our basic structured population model can be modified and applied to different scenarios and policies to make predictions about a number of potentially relevant quantities. We focus on the population dynamics in China under different control scenarios, paying particular attention to age and sex distributions.

3.1 Predictions and comparison to data from China

Refer to caption
Figure 5: Predictions and comparison with real data. (a) Net growth rates in 1981-2020, observed (“obs”) and predicted growth rates (starting from 1981 conditions) under different policies δ\delta. (b) Predictions of the female population in 2021-2100 under different values of δ\delta.

First, we use parameters inferred from 1981 Chinese data in our model to predict population growth for different values of δ\delta. When we compare predicted net growth rates with those derived from 1981-2020 data, shown in Fig. 5(a), we see that (i) during 1981-1990, the observed growth rate is close to that when δ=2\delta=2111This means that there was effectively no interbirth period policy and that the the adjusted birth rate β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) was not changed much during the lax birth-control policies during this period (Li and Wong, 2020).; (ii) from 1991 to 2010, the observed growth rate was close to that predicted from a model with δ=5\delta=5, possibly due to harsher policies like coerced abortion (Nie, 1999); (iii) after 2011, the observed growth rate rose to a level close to that of a model with δ=34\delta=3\sim 4, indicating a de facto relaxation of the one-child policy. Indeed, after 2011, policies that encouraged births were initiated. Starting in 2011, a couple was allowed to have up to two children if both parents never had siblings. Then, starting in 2014, a couple can have up to two children if at least one of the parents never had a sibling. Finally, starting in 2016, couples could bear up to two children regardless of their sibling status (Kane and Li, 2021). These policies might explain the flattening and subsequent increase in the net growth rate starting about 2011. However, the effects of these policies might be temporary. After the two-child policy in 2016, the net growth rate increased to the level consistent with a δ=3\delta=3 model but soon returned to the level closer a δ=4\delta=4 model. The actual growth rate is higher than in the δ=\delta=\infty, strict one-child policy model. This indicates that many couples had, legally or illegally, more than one child.

Starting in 2021, a new policy allows any couple to have up to three children without penalty. We make different predictions for the effect of this three-child policy. The optimistic prediction is that the policy can fully stimulate childbearing to the point that the net growth rate can reach the level predicted by a δ=2\delta=2 model, but this could be realized only if behavior and cultural-economic changes have not affected an intrinsic propensity for childbearing. Another possibility is that the policy has no significant effect so that the net growth rate will only increase modestly and transiently before effectively reducing back to that consistent with a δ=4\delta=4 model. See Fig. 5(b) for different predictions of population over the 2021-2100 time frame.

3.2 Minimum childbearing age and population aging

Besides mandating a refractory period between births, another method of population control is to impose a minimum childbearing age. The minimum age amina_{\rm min} is thus set by policy rather than by physiology. For example, starting in 1985, in Yicheng county, Shanxi province, a couple could bear two children, but the first child was allowed only after the mother turned 24, and the second child was allowed only after the mother turned 30 (Qin and Wang, 2017).222In China, the legal marriage age for females is 20 implying an existing soft constraint of amin21a_{\rm min}\approx 21.

Refer to caption
Figure 6: The effect of adjusting the minimum childbearing age. (a) Increasing the interbirth delay δ\delta and increasing the minimum childbearing age amina_{\min} have similar side effects of increasing the percentage of senior population. The red dashed line indicates a dangerous senior population percentage, 20%20\%. (b) Under the strict one-child policy (namely, δ=\delta=\infty), when we increase the minimum childbearing age amina_{\min}, the stationary net growth rate λ\lambda will first increase then decrease.

One side-effect of population control is a distribution shifted toward older ages. In China, the percentage of seniors (65+) increased from 5%5\% in 1981 to 13%13\% in 2020 (Man et al., 2021). Policies such as imposing interbirth delays δ\delta and minimum childbearing ages amina_{\min} can both affect the long term senior (65+) population. Fig. 6(a) shows a contour plot of the percentage of seniors as a function of imposed δ\delta and amina_{\min}. In order to maintain the senior population under 20%20\% (the red dashed line), the overall policy must not be too drastic. Nonetheless, with two strategies, a balanced combination can be used. For example, one can set amin=26,δ=2a_{\min}=26,\delta=2, or amin=24,δ=4a_{\min}=24,\delta=4, or amin=21,δ=5a_{\min}=21,\delta=5 and still prevent the senior population from exceeding 20%20\% far in the future.

Although increasing the minimum childbearing age amina_{\min} should reduce the rate of childbirth, we observe a counter-intuitive scenario in which the net growth rate is nonmonotonic in amina_{\min}. Under the strict one-child policy (i.e., δ=\delta=\infty), increasing amina_{\min} will first increase the stationary net growth rate λ\lambda before decreasing it, as shown in Fig. 6(b). Under a perpetual strict one-child policy, the population in each successive generation is roughly halved and the total number of future newborns is roughly the current population. Although decreasing amina_{\min} can temporarily increase the total population, it accelerates the “halving process” in the long run since the interval between successive generations is shorter. When amina_{\min} is not large, almost every woman can have one child anyway. Further increasing amina_{\min} will decrease λ\lambda as more women start to be pushed past their childbearing years without giving birth; thus, a maximum in the growth rate λ\lambda arises at amin29a_{\min}\approx 29.

3.3 Female population fraction and interbirth delay

We used η=0.48\eta=0.48, the fraction of female births 1981 China, to generate the results presented in Section 2. Due to subsequent sex-selective abortions biased towards males, the value of η\eta dropped to 0.450.45 in 2005 before gradually increasing (Zeng et al., 1992; Goodkind, 2011; Li and Meng, 2014).

Refer to caption
Figure 7: Dependence of the stationary female fraction on η\eta and δ\delta. Increasing the fraction of female births η\eta and the interbirth delay δ\delta can both increase the stationary female population fraction. The red dashed line indicates conditions for 50% females.

We can alter the value of η\eta and calculate the stationary female fraction of total population, which is also affected by the interbirth delay δ\delta. Fig. 7 illustrates the stationary female percentage as a function of η\eta and δ\delta. When δ=2\delta=2, the stationary female percentage is approximately 1% higher than the female percentage η\eta at birth. When we fix η\eta and increase δ\delta, the stationary female fraction also increases. When δ=\delta=\infty, the stationary female population is approximately 3% higher than η\eta. For larger δ\delta, the stationary age distribution is shifted to larger ages. Since the female death rate μf(a)\mu_{\rm f}(a) is lower than the male death rate μm(a)\mu_{\rm m}(a) at larger ages aa, the female percentage increases with age (in 1981 China, newborns were 48% female while 65+ seniors were 56% female).

3.4 Behavioral response to policies

We have discussed the policy of applying a refractory period between births and predicted its effects. We assume that the birth rate returns to normal after the refractory period, meaning that people obey this policy and do not respond with compensatory behaviors. In reality, people who want to have more children might mitigate the effects of control policies by, for example, giving birth again immediately after the end of the refractory period following the previous birth. In addition to this “catch up” strategy to recover from the “missed opportunity,” people might also prefer to have the first child earlier, so that the refractory period finishes at an younger age.

We propose a model that considers possible behavioral responses and compare it with a no-response model. (1) For females of age aa who have just finished their refractory period, the birth rate for the following year (only) will be set to β0(a)c1\beta_{0}(a)c_{1} instead of simply β0(a)\beta_{0}(a). We can model the compensatory increase of birth rate after the refractory period by c1=1+0.1×min{δ2,10}>1c_{1}=1+0.1\times\min\{\delta-2,10\}>1. When the refractory period δ\delta is longer, people are more likely to more quickly make up for the lost opportunity. (2) For females of age aa who have not had children, if a+δ40a+\delta\leq 40, the birth rate, instead of simply being β0(a)\beta_{0}(a), will be set to β0(a)c2\beta_{0}(a)c_{2}, where c2=1+0.05×min{δ2,10}c_{2}=1+0.05\times\min\{\delta-2,10\}. This means that females prefer to have the first child earlier, if they know that they are young enough to have another child after the refractory period (the age will be a+δa+\delta at that future time).

Refer to caption
Figure 8: Comparison of the predictions of models with and without behavioral response. (a) Effect of an imposed interbirth delay δ\delta on the asymptotic growth rate λ\lambda. The red curve depicts the no-response model, the same as the curve in Fig. 3(a). The blue curve is the growth rate associated with the behavioral response model (where β0(a)c1\beta_{0}(a)c_{1} and β0(a)c2\beta_{0}(a)c_{2} are used as birth rates). For a moderate refractory periods (δ=510\delta=5\sim 10), the behavioral response is equivalent to making δ\delta one year shorter. (b) Evolution of the total female population n(t)n(t) for different imposed delays between births. The red and blue curves represent populations associated with the no-response (same as in Fig. 4(b)) and behavioral response models, respectively. The solid, dashed, dotted, dash-dotted curves correspond to δ=3,4,7,15\delta=3,4,7,15 years, respectively. Behavioral responses have stronger effects on the total population when δ\delta is not too large.

Fig. 8 compares predictions from the standard no-response model (red) to those from a behavioral response model (blue). As expected, behavioral responses blunt the policy-induced decreases in the stationary growth rate (Fig. 8(a)) and the total population (Fig. 8(b)), resulting in higher-than-expected growth and populations. For an imposed δ\delta, a compensatory behavioral response model leads to a higher stationary growth rate. In other words, if the behavioral responses of this example are included, the imposed delay δ\delta would have to be about 1-2 years longer than in the absence of behavioral response in order to achieve the same overall growth rate (for intermediate delays δ515\delta\approx 5-15 years). However, if the refractory period is set very long (δ20\delta\gtrsim 20 years), our proposed behavioral responses are futile since females are irreversibly moved past their fertility window.

3.5 Comparison between China and Japan

We have examined the effect of applying a refractory period policy in China, which has implemented various birth-control policies over past four decades. To better study this interbirth delay, we apply our model to Japan, which does not have enforced polices on population control. We use Japan’s 2000 population data as a starting point (Statistics Bureau of Japan, 2001). For Japan, we use its 2000 birth rate, which was much lower than that of 1981 China.

Fig. 9 compares the stationary growth rates between China and Japan, imposing different refractory periods δ\delta. Since Japan has a much lower growth rate β0\beta_{0}, with the same δ\delta, the stationary growth rate of Japan is lower than that of China. When δ\delta is sufficiently large, since each female can have at most one child, the difference between China and Japan diminishes. In fact, the limiting high-δ\delta stationary growth rate of Japan is slightly higher than that of China. Since the childbearing age is older in Japan, the gap between two successive generations is longer. As observed in Fig. 6(b), under large-δ\delta, sub-replacement conditions, a moderately longer gap between generations can increase the stationary (very long term) growth rate.

Refer to caption
Figure 9: Effect of an imposed interbirth delay δ\delta on the asymptotic growth rate λ\lambda, using birth rate data from China and Japan. The red curve is the asymptotic growth rate calculated from 1981 China data, the same as that shown in Fig. 3(a). The blue curve is the asymptotic growth rate calculated from 2000 Japan data. Since Japan has a much lower birth rate, even without a refractory period policy (δ=2\delta=2), the stationary growth rate is negative. When δ\delta is large enough, each female can have at most one child, and the asymptotic rate of population decay for China and Japan are nearly the same. However, under this large-δ\delta sub-replacement limit, the long term growth rate for Japan can actually be slightly larger (less negative) than that of China.

4 Summary and Conclusions

We have formulated a “continuum” of birth-control policies for population management in which the strict one-child policy is a limiting case. Our approach is based on explicitly incorporating a refractory period between births. In general, our age- and gestation-period structured model can also apply to organisms in which the gestation time is appreciable compared to an organism’s window of fertility. For example, animals such as the Greater cane rat (Thryonomys swinderianus), the Pacarana (Dinomys branickii) and the Steenbok (Raphicerus campestris) have gestation periods approximately 15%15\% of their fertility window (Woods and Kilpatrick, 2005). Although a single gestation period is about 3%3\% of the childbearing period in humans (Tacutu et al., 2018), socially imposed refractory periods can be much longer (and infinite in a strict one-child policy). Thus, our model provides a natural way to test how imposed tunable interbirth refractory periods δ\delta affect the predicted total female population and its steady-state age distribution. For long delays δ\delta, the model approaches the strict one-child policy as a larger fraction of women are pushed past menopause.

In our mathematical analysis, we found a number of analytic or closed-form solutions to relevant demographic quantities such as the steady-state age distribution. We then considered an alternative scenario in which “lax” birth control policies that was being implemented in 1981 are kept, along with an additional policy of an imposed refractory period between births. Using 1981 as the starting point, we predicted population levels and compared them to the actual, realized populations. By applying a refractory period δ\delta between births and using 1981 China birth rates, we provided a retrospective analysis and arrived at a number of quantitative conclusions. Our analyses assumed that the birth rate β0\beta_{0} and death rate μ\mu did not change in the intervening years and that the population adhered to the birth-control policies without further behavioral responses. We concluded that: (i) When δ3.2\delta\gtrsim 3.2 years, the total population will not grow in the long run (Fig. 3(a)); (ii) When δ4\delta\geq 4 years, the total population in China would have always been maintained under 1.45 billion (Fig. 4(b)); (iii) When δ6\delta\geq 6 years, the net growth rates during 1990-2010 (when a harsher one-child policy was applied) would be as low as what was realized (Fig. 5(a)); (iv) Without increasing the minimum childbearing age, when δ5\delta\leq 5 years, the stationary senior population would be maintained under 20%20\% (Fig. 6(a)).

Such predictions assume the adjusted birth rate β0(a)\beta_{0}(a) does not change over time. This assumption is definitely unrealistic, since many important socio-economic factors can affect birth rate distributions. The decrease of birth rate in China (illustrated in Fig. 4(a)) is not due solely to birth-control policies. After 1980, female education increased, which had the statistically significant effect of decreasing the birth rate (Lan and Kuang, 2016). Additional evidence consistent with an extra-policy influence on birth rates in China is the increase in the average age of first childbirth (which one expects to be less affected by policies) from 24.3 years to 26.9 years from 2006 to 2016 (He et al., 2019). Moreover, we expect behavioral responses to policies that could mitigate their effectiveness. Since it is difficult to separate and quantify the effects of socio-economic factors and behavioral responses on birth rates, we did not explicitly incorporate these factors in our model. Nonetheless, we discussed how policies can be implemented through different modifications of age- and refractory period-dependent birth rate functions. For example, we considered a population-control policy whereby a minimum birth age amina_{\rm min} is imposed. Here, we found the counterintuitive result that under a strict one-child policy, increasing amina_{\min} first increases the stationary net growth rate, before decreasing it as amina_{\min} is further increased.

Age-structured models can also be generalized to include additional subpopulations, such as those arising in cell division (Xia et al., 2020) and disease propagation (Kang and Ruan, 2021) models. For example, in the birth control context, different generations and family structure can be enumerated in order to predict the effects of policies such as those implemented in 2011 and 2014 that consider the sibling status of would-be parents, allowing those without siblings more latitude in childbirth. Additional concepts from sociology and response to socioeconomic and political influences can also potentially be integrated for a more complete framework of population dynamics and demography. The ideas and mathematical tools in this paper can be adapted to other fields. For example, an economist or a sociologist might study the cultural norms regarding child spacing and use our models to connect child spacing to growth rates.

Data accessibility

Data and relevant code for this research work are stored in GitHub:
https://github.com/YueWangMathbio/ChildPolicy
and have been archived within the Zenodo repository:
https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.6394805.

Authors’ contributions

All authors collected and reviewed the literature, developed the model and analysis, and wrote drafts of the manuscript. YW and RD analyzed data and developed the computational methodology. All authors contributed to visualization and editing of the manuscript. All authors gave final approval for publication and agreed to be held accountable for the work performed therein.

Competing interests

We declare we have no competing interests.

Funding

This work was supported by grants from the NIH through grant R01HL146552 and the Army Research Office through grant W911NF-18-1-0345. The authors also thank the Collaboratory in Institute for Quantitative and Computational Biosciences at UCLA for support to RD.

Mathematical Appendices

Appendix A The equation of ftot(t,a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a)

We show by direct substitution that the total female population density ftot(t,a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a) satisfies the standard age-structured McKendrick equation. Substitution of Eq. 2 into Eq. (5) and expanding,

tftot(t,a)+aftot(t,a)=tf0(t,a)+af0(t,a)+0atf(t,a,τ)dτ+0aaf(t,a,τ)dτ+f(t,a,a)+0aτf(t,a,τ)dτ0aτf(t,a,τ)dτ=(μf(a)+β0(a))f0(t,a)0a(μf(a)+β(a,τ))f(t,a,τ)dτ+f(t,a,a)f(t,a,a)+f(t,a,0)=μf(a)ftot(t,a)β0(a)f0(t,a)0aβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ)dτ+β0(a)f0(t,a)+0aβ(a,τ)f(t,a,τ)dτ=μf(a)ftot(t,a).\begin{split}\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f_{\rm tot}(t,a)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f_{\rm tot}(t,a)=&\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f_{0}(t,a)+\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f_{0}(t,a)\\ \>&+\int_{0}^{a}\!\frac{\partial}{\partial t}f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau+\int_{0}^{a}\!\frac{\partial}{\partial a}f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\\ \>&+f(t,a,a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!\frac{\partial}{\partial\tau}f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau-\int_{0}^{a}\!\frac{\partial}{\partial\tau}f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\\ =&-\left(\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta_{0}(a)\right)f_{0}(t,a)-\int_{0}^{a}\big{(}\mu_{\rm f}(a)+\beta(a,\tau)\big{)}f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\\ \>&+f(t,a,a)-f(t,a,a)+f(t,a,0)\\ =&-\mu_{\rm f}(a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a)-\beta_{0}(a)f_{0}(t,a)-\int_{0}^{a}\!\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\\ \>&+\beta_{0}(a)f_{0}(t,a)+\int_{0}^{a}\!\!\beta(a,\tau)f(t,a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\\ =&-\mu_{\rm f}(a)f_{\rm tot}(t,a).\end{split} (28)

Appendix B Relation between βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) and β0(a)\beta_{0}(a)

In this Appendix, we prove Eq. (19), the link between βeff(a)\beta_{\rm eff}(a) and β0(a)\beta_{0}(a). In the following, assume τδ\tau\leq\delta. In Eq. (23), β(a,aa+τ)=0\beta(a^{\prime},a^{\prime}-a+\tau)=0 for any aτ<a<aa-\tau<a^{\prime}<a. Thus, we have

h(a,τ)h(aτ,0)=exp[τλaτaμf(a)da],\frac{h(a,\tau)}{h(a-\tau,0)}=\exp\left[-\tau\lambda-\int_{a-\tau}^{a}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right], (29)

while from Eq. (17), we have

htot(a)htot(aτ)=exp[τλaτaμf(a)da].\frac{h_{\rm tot}(a)}{h_{\rm tot}(a-\tau)}=\exp\left[-\tau\lambda-\int_{a-\tau}^{a}\mu_{\rm f}(a^{\prime})\textrm{d}a^{\prime}\right]. (30)

Thus,

htot(a)htot(aτ)=h(a,τ)h(aτ,0).\frac{h_{\rm tot}(a)}{h_{\rm tot}(a-\tau)}=\frac{h(a,\tau)}{h(a-\tau,0)}. (31)

From Eq. (15d) and Eq. (18), we have

h(aτ,0)=βeff(aτ)htot(aτ).h(a-\tau,0)=\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)h_{\rm tot}(a-\tau). (32)

Upon combining Eq. (31) and Eq. (32), we arrive at

h(a,τ)=βeff(aτ)htot(a).h(a,\tau)=\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)h_{\rm tot}(a). (33)

Since Eq. (33) is valid for any τδ\tau\leq\delta, we have

0δβeff(aτ)dτ=0δh(a,τ)dτhtot(a).\int_{0}^{\delta}\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)\textrm{d}\tau=\frac{\int_{0}^{\delta}h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}{h_{\rm tot}(a)}. (34)

Eq. (18) can be transformed into

βeff(a)=β0(a)h0(a)+δah(a,τ)dτhtot(a)=β0(a)[10δh(a,τ)dτhtot(a)].\beta_{\rm eff}(a)=\beta_{0}(a)\frac{h_{0}(a)+\int_{\delta}^{a}\!h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}{h_{\rm tot}(a)}=\beta_{0}(a)\left[1-\frac{\int_{0}^{\delta}\!h(a,\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}{h_{\rm tot}(a)}\right]. (35)

Combining Eq. (34) and Eq. (35), we obtain βeff(a)=β0(a)[10δβeff(aτ)dτ]\beta_{\rm eff}(a)=\beta_{0}(a)\left[1-\int_{0}^{\delta}\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)\textrm{d}\tau\right] and thus

β0(a)=βeff(a)10δβeff(aτ)dτ.\beta_{0}(a)=\frac{\beta_{\text{eff}}(a)}{1-\int_{0}^{\delta}\beta_{\text{eff}}(a-\tau)\textrm{d}\tau}. (36)

References

  • Arino [1995] Ovide Arino. A survey of structured cell population dynamics. Acta Biotheoretica, 43(1-2):3–25, jun 1995.
  • Bacaër [2011] Nicolas Bacaër. A Short History of Mathematical Population Dynamics. Springer Science & Business Media, 2011.
  • Bongaarts and Greenhalgh [1985] John Bongaarts and Susan Greenhalgh. An alternative to the one-child policy in china. Population and Development Review, 11:585–617, 1985.
  • Chou and Greenman [2016] Tom Chou and Chris D. Greenman. A hierarchical kinetic theory of birth, death andfission in age-structured interacting populations. Journal of Statistical Physics, 164:49–76, 2016.
  • Falkenburg [1973] Donald R. Falkenburg. Optimal control in age dependent populations, pages 112–117. IEEE, New York, NY, 1973.
  • Feeney and Yu [1987] Griffith Feeney and Jingyuan Yu. Period parity progression measures of fertility in China. Population Studies, 41(1):77–102, 1987.
  • Goodkind [2011] Daniel Goodkind. Child underreporting, fertility, and sex ratio imbalance in China. Demography, 48(1):291–316, 2011.
  • Greenhalgh [2004] Susan Greenhalgh. Science, Modernity, and the Making of China’s One-Child Policy. Population and Development Review, 29(2):163–196, jan 2004. ISSN 0098-7921. doi: 10.1111/j.1728-4457.2003.00163.x.
  • Greenman [2017] Chris D. Greenman. A path integral approach to age dependent branching processes. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, 2017(3):033101, 2017.
  • Greenman and Chou [2016] Chris D. Greenman and Tom Chou. A kinetic theory for age-structured stochastic birth-death processes. Physical Review E, 93(1), jan 2016.
  • Gurtin and MacCamy [1974] M. Gurtin and R. C. MacCamy. Non-linear age-dependent population dynamics. Arch. Ration. Mech. Anal., 54:281–300, 1974.
  • He et al. [2019] Dan He, Xuying Zhang, Ya’er Zhuang, Zhili Wang, and Yu Jiang. China fertility report, 2006–2016. China Popul. Dev. Stud., 2(4):430–439, 2019.
  • Hritonenko and Yatsenko [2010] Natali Hritonenko and Yuri Yatsenko. Age-Structured PDEs in Economics, Ecology, and Demography: Optimal Control and Sustainability. Mathematical Population Studies, 17(4):191–214, 2010.
  • Jiang et al. [2017] Da-Quan Jiang, Yue Wang, and Da Zhou. Phenotypic equilibrium as probabilistic convergence in multi-phenotype cell population dynamics. PLoS One, 12(2):e0170916, 2017.
  • Kane and Li [2021] Danielle Kane and Ke Li. Fertility cultures and childbearing desire after the two-child policy: evidence from southwest China. Journal of Family Studies, pages 1–19, 2021.
  • Kang and Ruan [2021] H. Kang and S. Ruan. Mathematical analysis on an age-structured SIS epidemic model with nonlocal diffusion. J. Math. Biol., 83:5, 2021.
  • Kermack and McKendrick [1927] W. O. Kermack and A. G. McKendrick. Contributions to the mathematical theory of epidemics. I. Proceedingsof the Royal Society, 115A:700–721, 1927. ISSN 0092-8240. doi: 10.1016/S0092-8240(05)80040-0.
  • Keyfitz and Keyfitz [1997] B. L. Keyfitz and N. Keyfitz. The McKendrick partial differential equation and its uses in epidemiology and population study. Mathl. Comput. Modelling, 26:1–9, 1997.
  • Lan and Kuang [2016] Manyu Lan and Yaoqiu Kuang. The impact of women’s education, workforce experience, and the one child policy on fertility in China: a census study in Guangdong, China. Springerplus, 5(1):1–12, 2016.
  • Langhaar [1972] H. L. Langhaar. General Population Theory in the Age-Time Continuum. Journal of the Franklin Institute, 293:199–214, 1972.
  • Li and Meng [2014] Hongbin Li and Lingsheng Meng. High sex ratio in china: Causes and consequences. In Shenggen Fan, Ravi Kanbur, Shang-Jin Wei, and Xiaobo Zhang, editors, The Oxford Companion to the Economics of China, chapter 81. Oxford Scholarship Online, 2014.
  • Li and Wong [2020] Wei Li and Wilson Wong. Advocacy coalitions, policy stability, and policy change in China: The case of birth control policy, 1980–2015. Policy Studies Journal, 48(3):645–671, 2020.
  • Man et al. [2021] Wang Man, Shaobin Wang, and Hao Yang. Exploring the spatial-temporal distribution and evolution of population aging and social-economic indicators in China. BMC Public Health, 21(1):1–13, 2021.
  • McKendrick [1926] A. G. McKendrick. Applications of mathematics to medical problems. Proc. Edinburgh Math. Soc., 44:98–130, 1926.
  • Nie [1999] Jing-Bao Nie. The problem of coerced abortion in China and related ethical issues. Cambridge Quarterly of Healthcare Ethics, 8(4):463–475, 1999.
  • Perthame [2007] Benoît Perthame. Transport Equations in Biology. Birkhäuser Basel, Basel, 2007. ISBN 978-3-7643-7841-7.
  • Pollard [1973] J.H. Pollard. Mathematical Models for the Growth of Human Population. Cambridge University Press, 1973.
  • Population Census Office under the State Council [1985] Population Census Office under the State Council, editor. 1982 Population Census of China (in Chinese). China Statistics Press, 1985.
  • Qin and Wang [2017] Yu Qin and Fei Wang. Too early or too late: What have we learned from the 30-year two-child policy experiment in Yicheng, China? Demographic Research, 37:929–956, 2017.
  • Song [1980] Jian Song. Bilinear optimal control with constraints in population systems (in Chinese). Zidonghua Xuebao, 6:241–249, 1980.
  • Song [1982] Jian Song. Some developments in mathematical demography and their application to the People’s Republic of China. Theoretical Population Biology, 22(3):382–391, 1982. ISSN 0040-5809. doi: 10.1016/0040-5809(82)90051-X.
  • Song et al. [1988] Jian Song, Deyong Kong, and Jingyuan Yu. Population System Control. Mathematical and Computational Modelling, 11:11–16, 1988.
  • Statistics Bureau of Japan [2001] Statistics Bureau of Japan, editor. 2000 Population Census of Japan (in Japanese). Japan Statistical Society, 2001.
  • Tacutu et al. [2018] Robi Tacutu, Daniel Thornton, Emily Johnson, Arie Budovsky, Diogo Barardo, Thomas Craig, Eugene Diana, Gilad Lehmann, Dmitri Toren, Jingwei Wang, Vadim E. Fraifeld, and João P. de Magalhães. Human Ageing Genomic Resources: New and updated databases. Nucleic Acids Research, 46(D1):D1083–D1090, jan 2018. ISSN 1362-4962. doi: 10.1093/nar/gkx1042.
  • Tuljapurkar [1983] Shripad Tuljapurkar. Transient dynamics of yeast populations. Mathematical biosciences, 64(2):157–167, 1983.
  • von Foerster [1959] H. von Foerster. Some remarks on changing populations in The Kinetics of Cell Proliferation. Springer, 1959.
  • Woods and Kilpatrick [2005] C. A. Woods and C. W. Kilpatrick. Infraorder hystricognathi. In D. E. Wilson and D. M. Reeder, editors, Mammal species of the world: A taxonomic and geographic reference, 3rd ed., page 1538. Johns Hopkins University Press, 2005.
  • Xia and Chou [2021] Mingtao Xia and Tom Chou. Kinetic theory for structured populations:application to stochastic sizer-timer models of cell proliferation. Journal of Physics A: Mathematical and Theoretical, 54:385601, 2021.
  • Xia et al. [2020] Mingtao Xia, Chris D. Greenman, and Tom Chou. PDE models of adder mechanisms in cellular proliferation. SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics, 80(3):1307–1335, 2020.
  • Xu et al. [2009] Fenglian Xu, Liqian Qiu, Colin W Binns, and Xiaoxian Liu. Breastfeeding in China: a review. Int. Breastfeed. J., 4(1):1–15, 2009.
  • Zeng et al. [1992] Y. Zeng, P. Tu, B. Gu, Y. Xu, B. Li, and Y. Li. Sex ratio of china’s population deserves attention. China Population Today, 9(6):3–5, 1992.