This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

Present address: ]Los Alamos National Laboratory, Los Alamos, New Mexico 87545

Mean-field theory of an asset exchange model with economic growth and wealth distribution

W. Klein [email protected] Department of Physics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215 Center for Computational Science, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215    N. Lubbers [ Department of Physics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215    Kang K. L. Liu Department of Physics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215    T. Khouw Department of Physics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215    Harvey Gould Department of Physics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts 02215 Department of Physics, Clark University, Worcester, Massachusetts 01610
Abstract

We develop a mean-field theory of the growth, exchange and distribution (GED) model introduced by Kang et al. (preceding paper) that accurately describes the phase transition in the limit that the number of agents NN approaches infinity. The GED model is a generalization of the Yard-Sale model in which the additional wealth added by economic growth is nonuniformly distributed to the agents according to their wealth in a way determined by the parameter λ\lambda. The model was shown numerically to have a phase transition at λ=1\lambda=1 and be characterized by critical exponents and critical slowing down. Our mean-field treatment of the GED model correctly predicts the existence of the phase transition, critical slowing down, the values of the critical exponents, and introduces an energy whose probability satisfies the Boltzmann distribution for λ<1\lambda<1, implying that the system is in thermodynamic equilibrium in the limit that NN\to\infty. We show that the values of the critical exponents obtained by varying λ\lambda for a fixed value of NN do not satisfy the usual scaling laws, but do satisfy scaling if a combination of parameters, which we refer to as the Ginzburg parameter, is much greater than one and is held constant. We discuss possible implications of our results for understanding economic systems and the subtle nature of the mean-field limit in systems with both additive and multiplicative noise.

I Introduction

Agent-based asset exchange models have become useful aem1 ; aem2 ; krapiv ; aem3 ; aem4 ; aem5 ; oneofthefirst ; ijmp ; hayes ; Burda ; Chakraborti2 for studying the effects of chance on the distribution of wealth. These models consist of NN agents that can exchange wealth through pairwise encounters. Examples of the exchange mechanism include the transfer of a fixed amount of wealth and the exchange of a fixed percentage of the average of the wealth of the two agents. The common feature of these models is that the winner in the exchange is determined by chance.

Of particular interest is the Yard-Sale model aem2 ; oneofthefirst ; hayes ; popbogo ; ijmp ; Burda ; bogo ; bogo2 ; bogo3 ; devitt ; probyardsale ; Moukarzel ; rosser in which pairs of agents are chosen at random and one is designated as the winner with a probability usually taken to be 1/2. The winner receives a fraction ff of the wealth of the poorer agent. The result is that after many exchanges, one agent gains almost all of the wealth, a phenomena known as wealth condensation.

In this paper we study a generalization of the Yard-Sale model kang in which a fixed percentage μ\mu of the total wealth is added to the system after NN exchanges. The added wealth is distributed according to

Δwi(t)=μW(t)wiλ(t)j=1Nwjλ(t),\Delta w_{i}(t)=\mu W(t)\frac{w^{\lambda}_{i}(t)}{\sum_{j=1}^{N}w^{\lambda}_{j}(t)}, (1)

where wi(t)w_{i}(t) is the wealth of agent ii at time tt and λ0\lambda\geq 0 is the distribution parameter. The quantity μW(t)\mu W(t) is the change in the total wealth in the system at time tt due to economic growth, where W(t)W(t) is the total wealth of the system at time tt, and the parameter μ\mu is the rate of growth. One unit of time corresponds to N2N^{2} exchanges. This distribution mechanism is justified by economic data in the Appendix of Ref. kang, .

This model, which we denote as the growth, exchange and distribution (GED) model, was investigated numerically kang and shown to have a phase transition at λ=1\lambda=1. For 0<λ<10<\lambda<1 the wealth is not distributed uniformly, but wealth condensation is avoided. As λ\lambda approaches 1 from below, the wealth distribution becomes more skewed toward the rich. However, there is economic mobility and poorer agents can become richer and richer agents can become poorer. In addition, every agent’s wealth increases exponentially as eμte^{\mu t} due to economic growth as the system evolves with time. In contrast, for λ1\lambda\geq 1 there is wealth condensation as was found in the original Yard-Sale model (μ=0\mu=0), and there is no economic mobility.

Numerical investigations indicate that the phase transition at λ=1\lambda=1 is continuous kang . The order parameter ϕ\phi is defined as the fraction of the wealth held by all of the agents except the richest and goes to zero as λ1\lambda\rightarrow 1^{-} (for NN\rightarrow\infty). Three exponents were introduced in Ref. kang, to characterize the behavior of various quantities as λ1\lambda\to 1^{-}, including the order parameter ϕ(1λ)β\phi\sim(1-\lambda)^{\beta} and the susceptibility χ(1λ)γ\chi\sim(1-\lambda)^{-\gamma} (the variance of the order parameter). As we will discuss in Sec. IV, we can define the total energy of the system and introduce the exponent α\alpha to characterize the critical behavior of the nonanalytic part of the mean energy as (1λ)1α(1-\lambda)^{1-\alpha}. Similarly, we relate the specific heat to the variance of the energy and characterize its divergence as (1λ)α(1-\lambda)^{-\alpha}. Because there is no length scale in the GED model, there is no obvious way of defining a correlation length exponent.

Simulations at fixed values of NN in Ref. kang yield the estimates β0\beta\approx 0, γ1\gamma\approx 1, 1α11-\alpha\approx-1 and α2\alpha\approx 2. These values do not satisfy the scaling law scalingref

α+2β+γ=2,\alpha+2\beta+\gamma=2, (2)

and do not appear to correspond to any known universality class.

In this paper we present a mean-field treatment of the GED model and find that the interpretation of the critical exponents is subtle. The theory shows that if the critical behavior is interpreted correctly, the exponents do satisfy Eq. (2) with β=0\beta=0, γ=1\gamma=1 and α=1\alpha=1. Moreover, we can define an energy and a Hamiltonian that allows us to obtain an equilibrium (Boltzmann) description of the GED model in the limit that the number of agents NN\to\infty. The mean-field theory results are consistent with the simulations kang .

In addition to casting light on the nature of the critical point, the mean-field approach predicts that for λ<1\lambda<1, the wealth distribution can be made less skewed toward the rich by increased growth for fixed NN, λ\lambda, and ff. The mean-field approach also indicates that wealth inequality can be reduced for fixed λ<1\lambda<1 and fixed NN and μ\mu by decreasing the value of ff, corresponding to decreasing the magnitude of the noise. However, for λ1\lambda\geq 1, economic growth does not avoid wealth condensation, and there is no economic mobility.

The structure of the remainder of the paper is as follows. In Sec. II we construct an exact differential equation for the GED model and then introduce the mean-field approximation to the equation. In Sec. III we show that there is a phase transition at λ=1\lambda=1 with critical slowing down, and obtain the values of the critical exponents β\beta and γ\gamma. In Sec. IV we introduce the Ginzburg parameter, define the total energy of the system, and determine the critical exponent α\alpha. In Sec. V we compare the predicted mean-field exponents with the numerical estimates. We discuss the role of multiplicative noise in the GED model in Sec. VI and examine the relation between the GED model and the geometric random walk in Sec. VII. Finally in Sec. VIII, we discuss the implication of these results for critical phenomena in fully connected systems and systems with long but finite-range interactions, and discuss the implication of our results for the study of economic systems. Because the GED model is similar in several ways to the fully connected Ising model, we review some aspects of that model in the Appendix and discuss the Ginzburg criterion as a self-consistency check on the applicability of mean-field theory.

II Exact and Mean-Field Equations

The rate of change of the wealth of agent ii is given by a formally exact stochastic difference equation

Δwi(t)1\displaystyle\frac{\Delta w_{i}(t)}{1} =\displaystyle= fjΘ[wi(t)wj(t)]ηij(t)wj(t)\displaystyle f\sum_{j}\Theta\big{[}w_{i}(t)-w_{j}(t)\big{]}\eta_{ij}(t)w_{j}(t) (3)
+fj{1Θ[wi(t)wj(t)]}ηij(t)wi(t)+μW(t)wi(t)λS(t).\displaystyle{}+f\sum_{j}\Big{\{}1-\Theta\big{[}w_{i}(t)-w_{j}(t)\big{]}\Big{\}}\eta_{ij(t)}w_{i}(t)+\mu W(t)\frac{w_{i}(t)^{\lambda}}{S(t)}.

The denominator on the left-hand side of Eq. (3) is written as 1 to emphasize that Eq. (3) is a difference equation rather than a differential equation. Here

Θ(wiwj)={1(wiwj)0(wi<wj),\Theta\big{(}w_{i}-w_{j}\big{)}=\begin{cases}1&\big{(}w_{i}\geq w_{j}\big{)}\\ 0&\big{(}w_{i}<w_{j}\big{)},\end{cases} (4)

and

S(t)=iwiλ(t).S(t)=\sum_{i}w^{\lambda}_{i}(t). (5)

The parameter ff is the fraction of the poorer agents’s wealth that is exchanged, μ\mu is the fraction of the total wealth that is added after NN exchanges, the parameter λ\lambda determines the distribution of the added economic growth, and ηij(t)\eta_{ij}(t) for ıj\i\neq j is a time-dependent random matrix element such that

ηij(t)={0agents i and j do not exchange wealth1wealth is transferred from agent j to agent i1wealth is transferred from agent i to agent j.\eta_{ij}(t)=\begin{cases}0&\mbox{agents $i$ and $j$ do not exchange wealth}\\ 1&\mbox{wealth is transferred from agent $j$ to agent $i$}\\ -1&\mbox{wealth is transferred from agent $i$ to agent $j$}.\end{cases} (6)

(ηij=0\eta_{ij}=0 if i=ji=j.) The matrix elements of η\eta can be chosen from any probability distribution with the constraint that if ηij=±1\eta_{ij}=\pm 1, then ηji=1\eta_{ji}=\mp 1. This condition imposes the constraint that the exchange conserves the total wealth.

To obtain a differential equation we multiply and divide the denominator on the left-hand side of Eq. (3) by NN, the number of agents. Because we will take the limit NN\rightarrow\infty and take one time unit to correspond to N2N^{2} exchanges, we have that 1/Ndt1/N\rightarrow dt. Note that in the simulations of Ref. kang , NN exchanges was chosen as the unit of time. In this case each agent will, on the average, exchange wealth with only one other agent and hence one exchange described by the difference equation would not take place in an infinitesimal amount of time. One exchange per agent does take place in an infinitesimal time if one time unit corresponds to N2N^{2} exchanges during which each agent exchanges wealth with every other agent on the average.

The parameters ff and μ\mu in Eq. (3) are the rates of exchange and growth, respectively, and are defined per NN exchanges to be consistent with the simulations. To obtain a consistent differential equation, these rates need to be scaled by NN. We let

f=f0/N and μ=μ0/N,f=f_{0}/N\mbox{ and }\mu=\mu_{0}/N, (7)

and assume that f0f_{0} and μ0\mu_{0} are independent of NN. We will see that these theoretical considerations imply that the values of the parameters ff and μ\mu chosen in the simulations must be scaled with NN if the Ginzburg parameter is held fixed.

Because wealth is added to the system after every NN exchanges, the total wealth in the system at time tt is given by

W(t)=W(0)eμ0t.W(t)=W(0)e^{\mu_{0}t}. (8)

With these considerations Eq. (3) becomes

dwi(t)dt\displaystyle\frac{dw_{i}(t)}{dt} =f0jΘ[wi(t)wj(t)]ηij(t)wj(t)\displaystyle={f_{0}}\sum_{j}\Theta\big{[}w_{i}(t)-w_{j}(t)\big{]}\eta_{ij}(t)w_{j}(t)
+f0j{1Θ[wi(t)wj(t)]}ηij(t)wi(t)+μ0W(t)wi(t)λS(t).\displaystyle{}+{f_{0}}\sum_{j}\Big{\{}1-\Theta\big{[}w_{i}(t)-w_{j}(t)\big{]}\Big{\}}\eta_{ij}(t)w_{i}(t)+{\mu_{0}}W(t)\frac{w_{i}(t)^{\lambda}}{S(t)}. (9)

To obtain a mean-field theory, we choose an agent whose wealth is w(t)w(t) and let wmf(t)w_{\rm mf}(t) be the mean wealth of the remaining agents. That is,

wmf(t)=W(t)w(t)N1.w_{\rm mf}(t)=\frac{W(t)-w(t)}{N-1}. (10)

The mean-field version of Eq. (9) is

dw(t)dt\displaystyle\frac{dw(t)}{dt} =\displaystyle= f0Θ[w(t)wmf(t)]ηwmf(t)+f0[1Θ[w(t)wmf(t)]]ηw(t)\displaystyle f_{0}\Theta\big{[}w(t)-w_{\rm mf}(t)\big{]}\eta w_{\rm mf}(t)+f_{0}\Big{[}1-\Theta\big{[}w(t)-w_{\rm mf}(t)\big{]}\Big{]}\eta w(t) (11)
+μ0W(t)w(t)λS(t).\displaystyle{}+\mu_{0}W(t)\frac{w(t)^{\lambda}}{S(t)}.

The quantity S(t)S(t) defined in Eq. (5) becomes

S(t)=wλ(t)+(N1)wmfλ(t).S(t)=w^{\lambda}(t)+(N-1)w_{\rm mf}^{\lambda}(t). (12)

To obtain a mean-field description we have effectively coarse grained the exchanges between the chosen agent and the remaining N1N-1 agents in time, which implies a coarse graining of the noise associated with the coin flips that determine the exchange of wealth. By using the central limit theorem, we can take the noise in Eq. (11) to be random Gaussian. This assumption would not be valid if the chosen agent interacted with only one other agent in one unit of time. However, because the unit of time corresponds to N2N^{2} exchanges, the chosen agent interacts with N1N-1 other agents and coarse graining in time makes sense. The coarse graining of the noise is another reason why it is necessary to choose N2N^{2} exchanges to be one unit of time in the mean-field theory.

It will be convenient to write the growth term in Eq. (11) as

μ0W(t)wλ(t)S(t)=μ0W(t)[w(t)/W(t)]λ[w(t)/W(t)]λ+(N1)1λ[1w(t)/W(t)]λ,\mu_{0}W(t)\frac{w^{\lambda}(t)}{S(t)}=\mu_{0}W(t)\frac{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}, (13)

where we have used Eqs. (10) and (12) and divided the numerator and denominator by Wλ(t)W^{\lambda}(t).

To simplify Eq. (11), we first assume that w(t)<wmf(t)w(t)<w_{\rm mf}(t); that is, the wealth of the chosen agent is less than the mean wealth of the remaining N1N-1 agents. We use Eqs. (9) and (13) to obtain

dw(t)dt=f0η(t)w(t)+μ0W(t)[w(t)/W(t)]λ[w(t)/W(t)]λ+(N1)1λ[1w(t)/W(t)]λ.\frac{dw(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)w(t)+\mu_{0}W(t)\frac{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}. (14)

We divide both sides of Eq. (14) by W(t)W(t) and rewrite Eq. (14) as

ddt(w(t)W(t))=f0η(t)w(t)W(t)+μ0[w(t)/W(t)]λ[w(t)/W(t)]λ+(N1)1λ[1w(t)/W(t)]λμ0w(t)W(t),\frac{d}{dt}\Big{(}\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}\Big{)}=f_{0}\eta(t)\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}+\mu_{0}\frac{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}-\mu_{0}\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}, (15)

where we have used the relation [see Eq. (8)]

1W(t)dw(t)dt=ddt(w(t)W(t))+μ0w(t)W(t).\frac{1}{W(t)}\frac{dw(t)}{dt}=\frac{d}{dt}\Big{(}\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}\Big{)}+\mu_{0}\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}. (16)

We next introduce the scaled wealth fraction

x(t)w(t)W(t),x(t)\equiv\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}, (17)

and rewrite Eq. (15) as

dx(t)dt\displaystyle\frac{dx(t)}{dt} =R(x,η,t)\displaystyle=R(x,\eta,t) (18a)
R(x,η,t)\displaystyle R(x,\eta,t) f0η(t)x(t)+μ0x(t)λx(t)λ+(N1)1λ[1x(t)]λμ0x(t).\displaystyle\equiv f_{0}\eta(t)x(t)+\mu_{0}\frac{x(t)^{\lambda}}{x(t)^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-x(t)]^{\lambda}}-\mu_{0}x(t). (18b)

Equation (18) expresses the time-dependence of the wealth of the chosen agent in contact with a mean-field representing the mean wealth of the remaining agents. Hence, the wealth of the chosen agent is not conserved.

For μ0=0\mu_{0}=0, the total wealth WW is a constant because the noise η(t)\eta(t) that determines the wealth transfer from the mean-field wealth to the chosen agent is the negative of the noise that governs the wealth transfer from the chosen agent to the mean field.

It is easy to show that for zero noise, R(x,η=0,t)=0R(x,\eta=0,t)=0 for x=0x=0, 1, and 1/N1/N, and that these are the only fixed points of Eq. (18) for λ1\lambda\neq 1. To determine the stability of the fixed points, we calculate the derivative dR(x,η=0,t)/dxdR(x,\eta=0,t)/dx and obtain

dR(x,0,t)dx=μ0λxλ1xλ+(N1)1λ(1x)λμ0xλ[λxλ1λ(N1)1λ(1x)λ1][xλ+(N1)1λ(1x)λ]2μ0,\frac{dR(x,0,t)}{dx}=\mu_{0}\frac{\lambda x^{\lambda-1}}{x^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}(1-x)^{\lambda}}-\mu_{0}\frac{x^{\lambda}[\lambda x^{\lambda-1}-\lambda(N-1)^{1-\lambda}(1-x)^{\lambda-1}]}{[x^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}(1-x)^{\lambda}]^{2}}-\mu_{0}, (19)

where xx(t)x\equiv x(t). For λ<1\lambda<1, the derivatives at x=0x=0 and x=1x=1 are equal to \infty, which implies that these fixed points are unstable. The derivative at x=1/Nx=1/N is equal to μ0(λ1)\mu_{0}(\lambda-1), and hence the fixed point at x=1/Nx=1/N is stable for λ<1\lambda<1. For λ>1\lambda>1 the derivative at x=1/Nx=1/N is positive so that this fixed point is unstable. The derivative at x=0x=0 and x=1x=1 equals 1-1, and hence these fixed points are stable.

We next return to Eq. (9) and consider the case for which w(t)>wmf(t)w(t)>w_{\rm mf}(t). The growth term is the same as before. The exchange term in Eq. (3), f0jΘ(wiwj)ηijwjf_{0}\sum_{j}\Theta\big{(}w_{i}-w_{j}\big{)}\eta_{ij}w_{j}, becomes f0ηwmff_{0}\eta w_{\rm mf}. We use Eq. (10) to write

dw(t)dt=f0η(t)W(t)w(t)N1+μ0W(t)[w(t)/W(t)]λ[w(t)/W(t)]λ+(N1)1λ[1w(t)/W(t)]λ.\frac{dw(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)\frac{W(t)-w(t)}{N-1}+\mu_{0}W(t)\frac{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}{[w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-w(t)/W(t)]^{\lambda}}. (20)

From Eq. (16) and the definition of x(t)x(t) in Eq. (17) we have

dx(t)dt=f0η(t)1x(t)N1+μ0x(t)λx(t)λ+(N1)1λ[1x(t)]λμ0x(t).\frac{dx(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)\frac{1-x(t)}{N-1}+\mu_{0}\frac{x(t)^{\lambda}}{x(t)^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-x(t)]^{\lambda}}-\mu_{0}x(t). (21)

Equation (18) for the poorer agent and Eq. (21) for the richer agent are the same except for the noise term, and hence the fixed points are the same. We again use Eq. (10) to rewrite Eq. (21) as

dx(t)dt=f0η(t)xmf(t)+μ0x(t)λx(t)λ+(N1)1λ[1x(t)]λμ0x(t),\frac{dx(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t){x}_{\rm mf}(t)+\mu_{0}\frac{x(t)^{\lambda}}{x(t)^{\lambda}+(N-1)^{1-\lambda}[1-x(t)]^{\lambda}}-\mu_{0}x(t), (22)

where xmf(t)=wmf(t)/W(t){x}_{\rm mf}(t)=w_{\rm mf}(t)/W(t) is the fraction of the mean field agent’s rescaled wealth. Note that x(t)x(t) is of order 1/N1/N as is xmf(t){x}_{\rm mf}(t). Equation (22) will be used in Sec. III to discuss the phase transition and the critical exponents.

In summary, the fixed points for all values of λ\lambda are x=0x=0, 1, and 1/N1/N for the mean-field equations describing the wealth evolution of either the richer or poorer agent. For λ<1\lambda<1, the fixed points at 0 and 1 are unstable, and the fixed point at 1/N1/N is stable, corresponding to all agents having an equal share of the total wealth on average. For λ>1\lambda>1, the fixed points at 0 and 1 are stable, and the fixed point at x=1/Nx=1/N is unstable, which implies that if all the agents are assigned an equal amount of wealth at t=0t=0, one agent will eventually accumulate all the wealth in a simulation of the model. Note that if we use the equation for which the chosen agent is richer than the “mean field” agent, then the stable fixed point reached when λ>1\lambda>1 is x=1x=1; similarly, if we chose the equation for which the chosen agent is poorer than the mean field agent, the stable fixed point reached for λ>1\lambda>1 is x=0x=0.

III The Phase Transition

To analyze the phase transition at λ=1\lambda=1, we investigate Eq. (22), the mean-field differential equation for the richer agent, for x1/Nx\sim 1/N and λ\lambda close to 11^{-}. We let

x(t)=1Nδ(t),x(t)=\frac{1}{N}-\delta(t), (23)

assume Nδ1N\delta\ll 1, and expand the second term on the right-hand side of Eq. (18b) to first order in NδN\delta. After some straightforward algebra we find that

dδ(t)dt=f0η(t)xmf(t)μ0(1λ)δ(t),\frac{d\delta(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)x_{\rm mf}(t)-\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)\delta(t), (24)

We multiply both sides of Eq. (24) by NN to obtain

dNδ(t)dt=f0η(t)w~mfμ0(1λ)Nδ(t),\frac{dN\delta(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t){\tilde{w}}_{\rm mf}-\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)N\delta(t), (25)

where w~mf=Nxmf{\tilde{w}}_{\rm mf}=Nx_{\rm mf}. We write w~mf=1Nδ{\tilde{w}}_{\rm mf}=1-N\delta, let

ϕ=Nδ,\phi=N\delta, (26)

and rewrite Eq. (25) as

dϕ(t)dt=f0η(t)[1ϕ(t)]μ0(1λ)ϕ(t).\frac{d\phi(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)\big{[}1-\phi(t)\big{]}-\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)\phi(t). (27)

As mentioned, we can assume the noise η(t)\eta(t) to be associated with a random Gaussian distribution of coin flips. Note that η\eta is the average over NN coin flips and hence should scale as N/N1/N{\sqrt{N}}/N\sim 1/{\sqrt{N}}. Hence η(t)\eta(t) in Eq. (27) is order 1/N1/\sqrt{N}, which implies that ϕ(t)1/N\phi(t)\sim 1/\sqrt{N} and justifies our neglect of terms higher than first order. Simulations in Ref. kang show that the fluctuations are dominated by those near the 1/N1/N fixed point.

Because ϕ(t)1/N1\phi(t)\sim 1/\sqrt{N}\ll 1 for N1N\gg 1, we can ignore ϕ(t)\phi(t) compared to one in Eq. (27) and obtain

dϕ(t)dt=f0η(t)(1λ)μ0ϕ(t).\frac{d\phi(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)-(1-\lambda)\mu_{0}\phi(t). (28)

The implications of neglecting the term f0ηϕ(t)f_{0}\eta\phi(t) in Eq. (27), which generates multiplicative noise, are discussed in Sec. VI. Here we note that the multiplicative noise term vanishes if the limit NN\rightarrow\infty is taken before the critical point is approached, that is, if the mean-field limit is taken before λ1\lambda\rightarrow 1. However, for finite NN the situation is more subtle.

The starting point for the derivation of Eq. (28) was Eq. (22), the mean-field equation for the richer chosen agent. If the chosen agent is poorer than the average of the other agents, similar arguments lead to the same equation as Eq. (28).

The form of Eq. (28) is identical to the linearized version of the Landau-Ginzburg equation ma ; kl-batrouni ; hh with ϕ\phi as the fluctuatng part of the order parameter. Hence, λ=1\lambda=1 corresponds to a phase transition as was found in simulations of the GED model kang . As for the usual Landau-Ginzburg equation, the factor of (1λ)(1-\lambda) sets the time scale for μ00\mu_{0}\neq 0. That is, as λ1\lambda\rightarrow 1^{-}, there is critical slowing down, and the system decorrelates on the time scale

τ1μ0(1λ).\tau\sim\frac{1}{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}. (29)

Because the stable fixed point of the poorer agent is zero for λ>1\lambda>1 [see Eq. (18)] and is one for the richer agent [see Eq. (21)], the order parameter is constant for both λ>1\lambda>1 and λ<1\lambda<1, which indicates that there is a discontinuous jump in the order parameter at λ=1\lambda=1. Hence, the exponent β\beta, which characterizes the way the order parameter approaches its value at the transition, is equal to zero.

To obtain the critical exponent γ\gamma, we adopt an approach introduced by Parisi and Sourlas ps and note that the measure of a random Gaussian noise is given by ps

P({ηj})\displaystyle P(\{\eta_{j}\}) =exp[βjηj2(t)dt]jδηjexp[βjηj2(t)dt],\displaystyle=\frac{\exp\Big{[}\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}-\beta\sum_{j}\eta_{j}^{2}(t)\,dt\Big{]}}{\!\int\!\prod_{j}\delta\eta_{j}\exp\Big{[}\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}-\beta\sum_{j}\eta_{j}^{2}(t)dt\Big{]}}, (30)
P(η)\displaystyle P(\eta) =exp[βNη2(t)dt]δηexp[βNη2(t)dt].\displaystyle=\frac{\exp\Big{[}\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}-\beta N\eta^{2}(t)\,dt\Big{]}}{\!\int\delta\eta\exp\Big{[}\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}-\beta N\eta^{2}(t)dt\Big{]}}. (31)

The factor of NN in the argument of the exponential in Eq. (31) comes from the fact that ηj(t)=η(t)\eta_{j}(t)=\eta(t) for all jj in the mean-field approach. This factor of NN is consistent with the argument that η(t)1/N\eta(t)\sim 1/{\sqrt{N}}. (In Ref. bigklein the factor of NN is not explicit, but is implicit in the integral over all space.)

We rewrite Eq. (28) as

1f0dϕ(t)dt+(1λ)f0μ0ϕ(t)=η(t),\frac{1}{f_{0}}\frac{d\phi(t)}{dt}+\frac{(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\mu_{0}\phi(t)=\eta(t), (32)

and replace η(t)\eta(t) in Eq. (31) by the left-hand side of Eq. (32). This replacement requires a Jacobian, but in this mean-field case the Jacobian is unity kl-batrouni . Hence the, probability of ϕ\phi is given by

P(ϕ)=exp{βN[1f0dϕ(t)dt+μ0(1λ)f0ϕ(t)]2𝑑t}δϕ(t)exp{βN[1f0dϕ(t)dt+μ0(1λ)f0ϕ(t)]2𝑑t}.P(\phi)=\frac{\exp\Big{\{}\!-\beta N\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}\Big{[}\dfrac{1}{f_{0}}\dfrac{d\phi(t)}{dt}+\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\phi(t)\Big{]}^{2}\!dt\Big{\}}}{\!\int\!\delta\phi(t)\exp\Big{\{}\!-\beta N\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}\Big{[}\dfrac{1}{f_{0}}\dfrac{d\phi(t)}{dt}+\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\phi(t)\Big{]}^{2}\!dt\Big{\}}}. (33)

We now assume that the system is in a steady state so that dϕ(t)/dt=0d\phi(t)/dt=0 over a time scale of the order of 1/μ0(1λ)1/\mu_{0}(1-\lambda). Hence, the average ϕ2\langle\phi^{2}\rangle is given by

ϕ2\displaystyle\langle\phi^{2}\rangle =δϕϕ2exp{βN𝑑t[μ0(1λ)f0ϕ]2}δϕexp{βN𝑑t[μ0(1λ)f0ϕ]2}\displaystyle=\frac{\!\int\delta\phi\,\phi^{2}\exp\Big{\{}-\beta N\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}dt\Big{[}\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\phi\Big{]}^{2}\Big{\}}}{\!\int\delta\phi\,\exp\Big{\{}-\beta N\!\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}dt\Big{[}\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\phi\Big{]}^{2}\Big{\}}} (34)
=δϕϕ2exp[βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2]δϕexp[βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2],\displaystyle=\frac{\int\delta\phi\,\phi^{2}\exp\Big{[}-\beta N\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\Big{]}}{\int\delta\phi\,\exp\bigg{[}-\beta N\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\bigg{]}}, (35)

where the range of integration over time is limited to the interval 1/μ0(1λ)1/\mu_{0}(1-\lambda).

Because we have assumed a steady state, the functional integral becomes a standard integral over ϕ\phi. We can take the limits of the integrals to be ±\pm\infty because the factor of N1N\gg 1 in the exponential keeps ϕ\phi of order 1/N1/\sqrt{N}. Hence, Eq. (35) now becomes

ϕ2=𝑑ϕϕ2exp{βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2}𝑑ϕexp{βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2}.\langle\phi^{2}\rangle=\frac{\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}d\phi\,\phi^{2}\exp\Big{\{}\!-\beta N\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\!\Big{\}}}{\int_{-\infty}^{\infty}d\phi\,\exp\Big{\{}-\beta N\dfrac{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\!\Big{\}}}. (36)

By using simple scaling arguments we see that the second moment of the probability distribution diverges as

ϕ2f02Nμ0(1λ).\langle\phi^{2}\rangle\sim\frac{f_{0}^{2}}{N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}. (37)

The fluctuating part of the order parameter ϕ=Nδ\phi=N\delta is analogous to the fluctuating part of the order parameter m=M/Nm=M/N of the fully connected Ising model, where MM is the total magnetization of the system and NN is the number of spins. To determine the susceptibility (per spin) of the Ising model, we need to multiply [m2m2][\langle m^{2}\rangle-\langle m\rangle^{2}] by NN. Because ϕ2=f02[Nμ0(1λ)]1\langle\phi^{2}\rangle=f_{0}^{2}[N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)]^{-1} [see Eq. (37)], the susceptibility (per agent) of the GED model is given by

χf02μ0(1λ).\chi\sim\frac{f_{0}^{2}}{\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}. (38)

We conclude that the susceptibility diverges near the phase transition with the exponent γ=1\gamma=1.

Note that we can relate the variance of ϕ\phi to the variance of the rescaled wealth. From the definition of δ(t)\delta(t) in Eq. (23) and the fact that x(t)=w(t)/W(t)x(t)=w(t)/W(t) is the rescaled wealth [see Eq. (17)], we have

ϕ(t)=1Nx(t)=1Nw(t)W(t)=1Nw~(t).\phi(t)=1-Nx(t)=1-N\frac{w(t)}{W(t)}=1-N\tilde{w}(t). (39)

We rescale the total wealth and hence the wealth of each agent so that W(t)=NW(t)=N after the increased wealth due to economic growth has been assigned. Hence w~\tilde{w} in Eq. (39) is the rescaled wealth of a single agent. Equation (39) will be useful in Sec. V where we compare the predictions of the theory to the results of the simulations in Ref. kang, .

IV The Energy and Specific Heat Exponents

From Eq. (33) we have that

P(ϕ)=exp{βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2}𝑑ϕexp{βNμ0(1λ)f02ϕ2},P(\phi)=\frac{\exp\Big{\{}\!-\beta N\mu_{0}\dfrac{(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\Big{\}}}{\!\int d\phi\exp\Big{\{}\!-\beta N\mu_{0}\dfrac{(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}\phi^{2}\Big{\}}}, (40)

assuming that the system is in a steady state. From the expression of the action or Hamiltonian in Eq. (40), where ϕ2\phi^{2} is multiplied by βNμ0(1λ)/f02\beta N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)/f_{0}^{2}, we see that the Ginzburg parameter for the GED model is given by (up to numerical factors)

G=Nμ0(1λ)f02.G=\frac{N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}^{2}}. (41)

To understand why GG on Eq. (41) can be interpreted as the Ginzburg parameter, compare the form of Eq. (40) with the form of the Hamiltonian for the fully connected Ising model in Eq. (57) and the dependences of GG in Eqs. (41) and (58) on their respective parameters.

The inverse temperature β\beta (not to be confused with the order parameter critical exponent), which arises from the amplitude of the Gaussian noise, will be absorbed in the parameter f0f_{0}. The association of β\beta with f0f_{0} is consistent with Eq. (32) in that we are relating the temperature to the amplitude of the noise and indicates that increasing the fraction of the poorer agent’s wealth transferred in an exchange is equivalent to increasing the amplitude of the noise.

The total energy for the GED model can be seen from the form of the action or the Hamiltonian in Eq. (40)

E=Nϕ2,E=N\phi^{2}, (42)

in analogy with the Landau-Ginzburg-Wilson free field or Gaussian action for the fully connected Ising model lou . Equations (39) and (42) imply that the total energy of a system of NN agents is given by

E\displaystyle E =i=1N(1w~i)2\displaystyle=\sum_{i=1}^{N}(1-\tilde{w}_{i})^{2} (43a)
=N+i=1Nw~i2,\displaystyle=-N+\sum_{i=1}^{N}\tilde{w}_{i}^{2}, (43b)

where we have used that fact that iw~i=N\sum_{i}\tilde{w}_{i}=N.

The existence of a quantity that can be interpreted as an energy implies that the probability density of the energy is given by the Boltzmann distribution for λ<1\lambda<1. The latter is consistent with simulations of the GED model kang . The existence of the Boltzmann distribution also implies that the system is in thermodynamic equilibrium and is not just in a steady state for λ<1\lambda<1.

From Eq. (40) we find that ϕ2f02/[Nμ0(1λ)]\langle\phi^{2}\rangle\sim f_{0}^{2}/[N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)]. Hence, we conclude from Eq. (42) that the mean energy per agent of the GED model scales as

ENf02Nμ0(1λ).\frac{\langle E\rangle}{N}\sim\frac{f_{0}^{2}}{N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}. (44)

Equation (44) suggests that the mean energy per agent diverges as (1λ)1(1-\lambda)^{-1} as λ1\lambda\rightarrow 1 for fixed NN, which is not physical. However, if we hold the Ginzburg parameter GG constant as λ1\lambda\to 1, we find no divergence (the exponent is zero), which removes the apparent nonphysical behavior. That is,

EN{(1λ)1(fixed N)G1(constant G).\frac{\langle E\rangle}{N}\sim\begin{cases}(1-\lambda)^{-1}&\mbox{(fixed $N$)}\\ G^{-1}&\mbox{(constant $G$)}.\end{cases} (45)

Equation (45) implies that the energy per agent is finite as we approach the critical point only if we hold GG constant.

Near the critical point the nonanalytic behavior of the mean energy per agent can be expressed as (1λ)1α(1-\lambda)^{1-\alpha}, where α\alpha is the specific heat exponent. Equation (45) for E/N\langle E\rangle/N for constant Ginzburg parameter implies that α=1\alpha=1. This result for α\alpha is what we would find if we require that β\beta, γ\gamma, and α\alpha to satisfy the scaling relation in Eq. (2) with β=0\beta=0 and γ=1\gamma=1.

We can also calculate α\alpha directly using the probability distribution in Eq. (40). To calculate the fluctuations in the total energy, we need to calculate the average of ϕ4\phi^{4}. If we apply the probability in Eq. (40), we find that the fluctuations in the energy per agent, and hence the specific heat is proportional as Nf4[μ0(1λ)]2Nf^{4}[\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)]^{-2}, where we have multiplied by NN as we did for the susceptibility per spin of the fully connected Ising model. Hence, the specific heat CC scales as

Cf04Nμ02(1λ)2,C\sim\frac{f_{0}^{4}}{N\mu_{0}^{2}(1-\lambda)^{2}}, (46)

and

C{(1λ)2(fixed N)(1λ)1(constant G).C\sim\begin{cases}(1-\lambda)^{-2}&\mbox{(fixed $N$)}\\ (1-\lambda)^{-1}&\mbox{(constant $G$)}.\end{cases} (47)

We see that if we keep the Ginzburg parameter constant, we find Cf02/[Gμ0(1λ)]C\sim f_{0}^{2}/[G\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)] and hence α=1\alpha=1. Note that if we do not keep GG constant, we would find α=2\alpha=2, which does not satisfy Eq. (2). As a consistency check, we can use Eqs. (44) and (46) to construct the Ginzburg parameter by comparing the fluctuations of the energy, that is, the heat capacity, to the mean energy:

NCE2f02Nμ0(1λ)=G1.\frac{NC}{{\langle E\rangle}^{2}}\propto\frac{f_{0}^{2}}{N\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}=G^{-1}. (48)

V Comparison with Simulations

The mean-field theory predictions for the exponents α=1\alpha=1, β=0\beta=0, and γ=1\gamma=1 are consistent with the simulation results reported in Ref. kang, for fixed GG. As discussed in Sec. III, mean-field theory also predicts that there is only one time scale near the phase transition and that the time scale diverges as (1λ)11-\lambda)^{-1} for fixed Ginzburg parameter, an example of critical slowing down [see Eq. (29)]. This prediction is consistent with the simulation results for the mixing time associated with the wealth metric kang and the energy decorrelation time, which were both found to diverge as (1λ)2(1-\lambda)^{-2} for fixed GG. The apparent discrepancy between the (1λ)2(1-\lambda)^{-2} divergence found in the simulations and the (1λ)1(1-\lambda)^{-1} divergence predicted by Eq. (29) is due to the difference in the choice of the unit of time in the simulation (NN exchanges) and in the mean-field theory (N2N^{2} exchanges). To account for the difference in time units, we need to divide the simulation result by NN with the result that N1(1λ)2(1λ)(1λ)2=(1λ)1N^{-1}(1-\lambda)^{-2}\sim(1-\lambda)(1-\lambda)^{-2}=(1-\lambda)^{-1}, where we have used the relation N(1λ)1N\propto(1-\lambda)^{-1} for fixed GG [see Eq. (41)].

The simulations for fixed GG indicate that the energy per agent approaches a constant as (1λ)0(1-\lambda)\rightarrow 0. This behavior is associated with the nonanalytic part of the energy per agent. This result for the λ\lambda-independence of the nonanalytic part of the energy per agent is inconsistent with the relation between the energy per agent and the specific heat, CE(λ)/λC\propto\partial\langle E(\lambda)\rangle/\partial\lambda. The (1λ)1(1-\lambda)^{-1} dependence of the specific heat for fixed GG near λ=1\lambda=1 suggests that the mean energy per agent could include a logarithmic dependence on λ\lambda. For example, the form, E/Na0+aL/log(1λ)\langle E\rangle/N\sim a_{0}+a_{L}/\log(1-\lambda), where a0a_{0} and aLa_{L} are independent of λ\lambda, implies that the specific heat scales as C[log(1λ)]2(1λ)1C\sim[\log(1-\lambda)]^{-2}(1-\lambda)^{-1}, thus yielding α=1\alpha=1 with logarithmic corrections, which standard mean-field theory cannot predict and are very difficult to detect in simulations.

There is also agreement between the exponents predicted by mean-field theory and those determined in the simulations when the measurements are done at fixed NN. From Eq. (44) we see that if NN is held constant, the mean energy per agent is predicted to diverge as (1λ)1(1-\lambda)^{-1}, which is consistent with the simulations kang , although this divergence, is unphysical because it implies that the mean energy per agent would become infinite. The exponent α\alpha is predicted to be equal to 2 for fixed NN, which is also in agreement with the simulations kang .

VI Multiplicative Noise

Refer to caption
Figure 1: Comparison of the wealth distribution P(w)P(w) for λ=0.998\lambda=0.998, N=5×105N=5\times 10^{5}, and M14M\approx 14 (red curve) with P(w)P(w) for λ=0.700\lambda=0.700, N=3333N=3333, and M173M\approx 173 (more sharply peaked black points). Both plots are for G=106G=10^{6}, with f0=0.01f_{0}=0.01, and μ0=0.1\mu_{0}=0.1. The two distributions would be identical if mean-field theory were exact. Plots of P(w)P(w) for closer values of MM [see Eq. (49)] are indistinguishable to the eye. Values of λ=0.7\lambda=0.7 and 0.998 were chosen so that the differences of P(w)P(w) are noticeable in the plot.)

A sensitive test of whether the system is in equilibrium is given by the form of the wealth distribution of the agents. The derivation of the Gaussian form of the wealth distribution [see Eq. (40)] assumes that the system is in a steady state and that GG\to\infty and implies that the distribution of the energy is a Boltzmann distribution. The wealth distribution P(w)P(w) in Eq. (40) is predicted to depend only on the value of GG and not on the parameters λ\lambda, f0f_{0}, and μ0\mu_{0} separately. Figure 1 shows the distribution of wealth for fixed G=106G=10^{6} and different values of λ\lambda and NN. Although the distributions are similar, we see that the wealth distribution is not invariant with respect to changes of λ\lambda for fixed GG, even though both distributions are well fit by a Gaussian. Similar changes in P(w)P(w) are found for changes in the other parameters for fixed GG.

To understand this behavior, we return to Eq. (27), the mean-field equation for the evolution of the wealth near the 1/N1/N fixed point, which we repeat here for convenience:

dϕ(t)dt=f0η(t)[1ϕ(t)]μ0(1λ)ϕ(t).\frac{d\phi(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)\big{[}1-\phi(t)\big{]}-\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)\phi(t). (27)

In Sec. III we argued that the multiplicative noise term f0ηϕf_{0}\eta\phi can be neglected because ϕ\phi is assumed to be much less than one. However, we retained the “driving” term μ0(1λ)ϕ\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)\phi and did not consider whether the multiplicative noise term was small compared to the driving term. To determine if this condition holds, we recall that the (average) noise η\eta is assumed to be random Gaussian. Our assumption that the amplitude of the Gaussian noise is proportional to 1/N1/\sqrt{N} is consistent with the dependence of the Gaussian noise in the mean-field limit of thermal models such as the Ising model (see, for example, Ref. bigklein, ).

Because the amplitude of the Gaussian noise is of order 1/N1/\sqrt{N}, we can neglect it compared to the driving term in Eq. (27) if f0/Nμ0(1λ)f_{0}/\sqrt{N}\ll\mu_{0}(1-\lambda), or

MNμ0(1λ)f01.M\equiv\frac{{\sqrt{N}}\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)}{f_{0}}\gg 1. (49)

Equation (49) defines the parameter MM. The condition M1M\gg 1 for the neglect of the multiplicative noise term, as well as the condition G1G\gg 1 has several implications.

  1. 1.

    Both GG and MM diverge in the mean-field limit for which first NN\to\infty and then the critical point at λ=1\lambda=1 is approached kac . If these limits are taken in this order, the mean-field treatment neglecting the multiplicative noise is exact (see Ref. bigklein and references therein).

  2. 2.

    A smaller value of f0f_{0} makes the system more describable by a mean-field treatment, which explains the better agreement of the exponents determined from the simulations for finite values of NN with the exponents calculated from a theory that neglects the multiplicative noise.

  3. 3.

    A large value of GG does not necessarily imply a large value of MM; that is, as λ1\lambda\to 1, the multiplicative noise can become important even though GG is still much greater than one.

  4. 4.

    The Ginzburg parameter GG controls the level of mean field and MM controls the influence of the multiplicative noise. It is necessary to keep both parameters constant to obtain results consistent with the mean-field theory. Because we cannot keep both parameters constant simultaneously, there will always be some inconsistency of the results for finite values of NN and GG. These inconsistencies can be minimized for sufficiently large NN by increasing μ0\mu_{0} or decreasing f0f_{0}. The point is that we need to be careful in interpreting the results of simulations. An example of the limitations of the mean-field theory and the neglect of both the additive and multiplicative noise terms is shown in Table 1. We see that both τE\tau_{E}, the energy decorrelation time, and τm\tau_{m}, the mixing time, depend weakly on ff in contrast to Eq. (29) which predicts that these times are independent of ff. The dependence of τE\tau_{E} and τm\tau_{m} on ff reflects the possible importance of the multiplicative noise.

NN ff μ\mu τm\tau_{m} τE\tau_{E}
5000 0.01 0.01 1034 229
5000 0.10 0.01 1229 149
5000 0.10 0.10 116 21
1000 0.10 0.10 115 21
Table 1: Summary of the dependence of the mixing time τm\tau_{m} and the energy decorrelation time τE\tau_{E} on NN, ff, and μ\mu for λ=0.8\lambda=0.8 (ff and μ\mu are not scaled). Comparison of the first two rows indicates that τm\tau_{m} and τE\tau_{E} depend weakly on ff for fixed NN and μ\mu. Comparison of the second and third rows suggests that τm\tau_{m} and τE\tau_{E} depend strongly on the value of μ\mu. Comparison of the third and fourth rows indicates that τm\tau_{m} and τE\tau_{E} are independent of NN. These dependencies are in qualitative agreement with Eq. (29).

VII Relation to the Geometric Random Walk

For either zero growth, μ0=0\mu_{0}=0, or for the critical point, λ=1\lambda=1, the mean-field equation for the rescaled wealth, Eq. (18), reduces to

dx(t)dt=f0η(t)x(t).\frac{dx(t)}{dt}=f_{0}\eta(t)x(t). (50)

If we use the Ito interpretation for the effect of the multiplicative noise in Eq. (50), the solution for x(t)x(t) is

x(t)=x(t=0)exp[f022t+f0Wt],x(t)=x(t=0)\exp\Big{[}-\frac{f_{0}^{2}}{2}t+f_{0}W_{t}\Big{]}, (51)

where WtW_{t} is a Brownian noise or Wiener process and is given by

Wt=tη(t)𝑑t.W_{t}=\!\int^{t}\!\eta(t^{\prime})dt^{\prime}. (52)

Because Eq. (50) results from either setting λ=1\lambda=1 or μ0=0\mu_{0}=0, Eq. (50) implies that the mean-field treatment of the GED model for μ0=0\mu_{0}=0 and λ1\lambda\neq 1 results in the same distribution as the geometric random walk without the drift term peters ; peters-klein . For λ=1\lambda=1 and μ00\mu_{0}\neq 0, the solution is eμ0tx(t)e^{\mu_{0}t}x(t), where x(t)x(t) is the solution with μ0=0\mu_{0}=0, and Eq. (51) describes the distribution of the geometric random walk with the drift or growth term peters ; peters-klein .

This result, which follows from the analysis of the mean-field equation, Eq. (18), is not applicable if NN is held constant because G=0G=0 for μ0=0\mu_{0}=0 or λ=1\lambda=1, and hence the mean-field approach does not apply. If we keep GG constant, Eq. (50) is applicable because the condition G1G\gg 1 is compatible with either μ00\mu_{0}\approx 0 or λ1\lambda\approx 1^{-}. To show numerically that the GED model reduces to the geometric random walk at the critical point involves fixing the value of GG and determining the form of the wealth distribution for λ1\lambda\neq 1 and μ0>0\mu_{0}>0 and then extrapolating the wealth distribution in the limit λ1\lambda\to 1 or μ00\mu_{0}\to 0. Such an extrapolation would be a difficult and time consuming process.

VIII Summary and Discussion

We have investigated a simple agent-based model of the economy in which two agents are chosen at random to exchange a fraction of the poorer agent’s wealth. Economic growth is distributed according to the parameter λ\lambda. The larger the value of λ\lambda, the greater the fraction of the growth that is distributed to the agents at the higher end of the wealth distribution. The model, which we call the GED model, was treated theoretically with a mean-field approach and was shown to have a critical point at λ=1\lambda=1, consistent with simulations kang . The critical exponents are consistent with scaling and the simulations if the Ginzburg parameter is large and held constant as the critical point is approached.

The agreement of the mean-field theory with the simulations implies that for finite but large GG and MM, the GED model can be characterized as near-mean-field bigklein . That is, the system is mean-field in the limit NN\rightarrow\infty, and is well approximated by mean-field theory if both NN and M1M\gg 1, provided that the Ginzburg parameter G1G\gg 1 and is held constant as the transition is approached.

The mean-field theory and the simulations raise some interesting questions about the relation between growth, uncertainty and wealth inequality and the applicability of statistical physics. The questions concerning statistical physics include the following:

  • The inclusion of distribution and growth allows the system to be treated by the methods of equilibrium statistical mechanics, but only if the distribution parameter λ<1\lambda<1 and in the limit that the number of agents NN\rightarrow\infty. A similar result holds for models of earthquake faults for long-range stress transfer bigklein ; rundle . It is unclear how many driven dissipative non-equilibrium systems become describable by equilibrium methods in the mean-field limit.

  • We used equilibrium methods to calculate the critical exponents in agreement with the simulations, but the exponent α\alpha associated with the specific heat is thermodynamically consistent only if the Ginsburg parameter is held constant. Similar results were found for the fully connected Ising model lou ; kangspecificheat . Insight into why holding GG constant is necessary will be discussed in detail in a future publication kangspecificheat .

  • A subtle feature of using a mean-field approach to treat the GED model for N1N\gg 1 but finite is the presence of multiplicative as well as additive noise. The effect of the multiplicative noise is controlled by the parameter MM defined in Eq. (49). From the agreement of the theory with the simulations, we conclude that the neglect of the multiplicative noise in the theory is a good approximation for M1M\gg 1. The role of multiplicative noise is of particular interest for models of the economy in light of the non-ergodicity of the geometric random walk, which includes multiplicative noise peters ; peters-klein .

  • To obtain an equilibrium description of critical point behavior, we defined an order parameter and then obtained the order parameter exponent β\beta and the susceptibility exponent γ\gamma. To obtain the specific heat exponent α\alpha, we defined an energy, which also allowed us to obtain the λ\lambda dependence of the energy as λ\lambda approaches its critical value. The definitions of the order parameter and the energy generate a thermodynamically consistent set of exponents that characterize the critical point. Is our choice of order parameter and energy unique, or are there other definitions that would lead to another set of thermodynamically consistent exponents?

Any statements about a system as complicated as the economy based on the simple GED model must be viewed with a considerable amount of caution. However, the results obtained from both the numerical and theoretical investigations of the GED model suggest some general properties of economic systems that are of potential interest.

  • The form of the exchange term in Eq. (3) assumes that the amount of the exchange is determined by the poorer agent. This assumption is a reasonable first approximation because in most exchanges of goods or services, the poorer of the two agents decides if they can afford the exchange. The fact that the wealth transferred is a percentage of the poorer agent’s wealth leads to the multiplicative part of the noise.

  • The exchange term in Eq. (3) also assumes that the winner of the exchange is based on the toss of a true coin. Such a toss assumes that both agents have equal knowledge of the worth of the exchange at the time of the exchange, so that any advantage enjoyed by the winning agent is gained by pure chance. The effect of biasing the coin toss to represent a superior knowledge of either the richer or poorer agent is a subject of future study Cardoso .

  • We found that if the distribution of the wealth generated by economic growth is not skewed too heavily toward the wealthy (λ<1\lambda<1), then every agent’s wealth grows exponentially with time. The distribution of wealth is not equal, but wealth condensation is avoided. As λ1\lambda\to 1^{-}, the wealth distribution becomes more skewed toward the wealthy, thus increasing inequality. The theory indicates that a more unequal distribution of added wealth due to growth can be overcome by either increasing the growth parameter μ0\mu_{0}, decreasing the uncertainty by decreasing f0f_{0}, or by increasing NN. The theory also indicates that there is a tipping point at λ=1\lambda=1, so that for λ1\lambda\geq 1, no increase of μ0\mu_{0} or decrease in f0f_{0} can overcome the inequality caused by the distribution of the growth favoring the wealthy. Although the GED model is very simple, this result raises the question of whether there is a tipping point in more realistic models of the economy. That is, can the distribution of the growth in wealth favor the rich to such an extent that the increased wealth (“a rising tide”) is no longer shared by the majority of people (“lifts all boats”), and the effect of the unequal added wealth distribution cannot be alleviated by increased growth or decreased uncertainty?

  • The theory suggests that as the number of agents NN is increased, with the parameters λ\lambda, f0f_{0}, and μ0\mu_{0} held fixed, the system becomes more describable by a mean-field approach. This result suggests that as globalization increases, mean-field models of the global economy might become more relevant and equilibrium methods might be more appropriate in contrast to economic models that are not ergodic peters ; peters-klein ; petersnature . We stress that an equilibrium treatment would be an approximation and be exact only for NN\rightarrow\infty, but might be a good approximation for N1N\gg 1, assuming that GG and MM are both much greater than one. The question of how the multiplicative noise would affect the system if simulated for a very long time is not clear. We found that if the effect of the multiplicative noise is increased by lowering MM, the wealth distribution develops a tail for large wealth, indicating that the multiplicative noise induces greater wealth inequality.

  • The model also suggests that increasing the noise amplitude f0f_{0} increases wealth inequality. In addition, the theory assumes that the parameters λ\lambda, f0f_{0}, and μ0\mu_{0} are independent. These parameters are not necessarily independent in actual economies, which raises the question of how these variables affect each other. For example, μ0\mu_{0} could be made to depend on λ0\lambda_{0}. If μ0\mu_{0} is increased as λ0\lambda_{0} is increased, this dependence would be a test (in the model) of the trickle down theory.

Besides the areas of future research raised by these questions, other areas include investigating the effect of growth in models on various network topologies and investigating different exchange mechanisms and how they affect the distribution of wealth when growth is added.

Appendix A Appendix: The Fully Connected Ising Model

It is useful to discuss the analogous equilibrium behavior of the fully connected Ising model. To do so, we first consider the long-range Ising model with interaction range RR in the limit that RR\to\infty.

The Landau-Ginzburg-Wilson Hamiltonian for the long-range Ising model in zero magnetic field is given by bigklein

H(ϕ(y))=𝑑y[R2(ϕ(y))2+ϵϕ2(y)+ϕ4(y)].H\big{(}\phi({\vec{y}})\big{)}=\!\int\!d{\vec{y}}\,\Big{[}R^{2}(\nabla\phi({\vec{y}}))^{2}+\epsilon\phi^{2}({\vec{y}})+\phi^{4}({\vec{y}})\Big{]}. (53)

The integral in Eq. (53) is over all space, ϵ=(TTc)/Tc\epsilon=(T-T_{c})/T_{c}, TcT_{c} is the critical temperature, and ϕ(y)\phi(\vec{y}) is the coarse grained magnetization.

Near the mean-field critical point we scale ϕ(y)\phi(\vec{y}) by ϵ1/2\epsilon^{1/2}, scale all lengths by Rϵ1/2R\epsilon^{-1/2}, and obtain

H((ψ(x))=Rdϵ2d/2dx[(ψ(x)2+ψ2(x)+ψ4(x)],H\big{(}(\psi({\vec{x}})\big{)}=R^{d}\epsilon^{2-d/2}\!\int d{\vec{x}}\,\Big{[}(\nabla\psi({\vec{x}})^{2}+\psi^{2}({\vec{x}})+\psi^{4}({\vec{x}})\Big{]}, (54)

where ψ(x)=ϵ1/2ϕ(y/R)\psi({\vec{x}})=\epsilon^{-1/2}\phi(\vec{y}/R) and x=y/Rϵ1/2{\vec{x}}=\vec{y}/R\epsilon^{-1/2}. The integral is over the volume in scaled coordinates. Because the functional integral over ψ(x)\psi({\vec{x}}) is damped for larger values of ψ\psi due to the Boltzmann factor eβH(ψ(x))e^{-\beta H(\psi({\vec{x}}))} and Rdϵ2d/21R^{d}\epsilon^{2-d/2}\gg 1, the rescaled magnetization ψ(x)\psi({\vec{x}}) satisfies the condition,

ψ(x)<1Rdϵ2d/2.\psi({\vec{x}})<{\sqrt{\frac{1}{R^{d}\epsilon^{2-d/2}}}}. (55)

For the fully connected Ising model we can ignore the gradient term in HH and take Rdϵ2d/2Nϵ2R^{d}\epsilon^{2-d/2}\rightarrow N\epsilon^{2}, and the integral in Eq. (54) becomes of order one.

To calculate the exponent β\beta for the fully connected Ising model, we take ϵ<0\epsilon<0 and write

H(ψ)=Nϵ2[ψ2+ψ4].H\big{(}\psi\big{)}=N\epsilon^{2}\big{[}-\psi^{2}+\psi^{4}\big{]}. (56)

The most probable value of ψ\psi is obtained by setting the derivative with respect to ψ\psi of H(ψ)H(\psi) equal to zero; the result is that the most probable value of ψ\psi is ϵ1/2\sim\epsilon^{1/2} and β=1/2\beta=1/2.

To calculate the isothermal susceptibility χ\chi for the fully connected Ising model, we can ignore the quadratic term in Eq. (56) and write the action of Hamiltonian as

H(ψ)=Nϵ2ψ2.H(\psi)=N\epsilon^{2}\psi^{2}. (57)

We determine the probability as a function of ψ\psi and multiply the average of ϵψ2\epsilon\psi^{2} (ϕ2\phi^{2}) by NN to obtain χϵ1\chi\sim\epsilon^{-1} as expected.

Note that the action in Eq. (57) is order one for the range of fluctuations in the fully connected Ising model; that is, ψ1/Nϵ2\psi\lesssim 1/{\sqrt{N\epsilon^{2}}}. Similarly, we expect the action in the GED model to also be of order one, not order NN.

The energy per spin of the fully connected Ising model is the square of the magnetization per spin bigklein . Hence the mean energy per spin is the average of ϵψ2=1/Nϵ\epsilon\psi^{2}=1/N\epsilon. This dependence on ϵ\epsilon seems nonphysical and seems to imply that the energy per spin diverges as ϵ0\epsilon\rightarrow 0. To understand this result and to calculate the specific heat, we introduce the Ginzburg criterion, which is a self-consistency check on the applicability of mean-field theory bigklein . For a mean-field theory to be a good description, the fluctuations of the order parameter must be small compared to the mean value of the order parameter. This requirement implies that

ξdχξ2dϕ2=1G1,\frac{\xi^{d}\chi}{\xi^{2d}\phi^{2}}=\frac{1}{G}\ll 1, (58)

where ξ\xi is the correlation length, χ\chi is the susceptibility, and dd is the spatial dimension. The Ginzburg parameter GG defined by Eq. (58) must be much greater than one for mean-field theory to be a good approximation. Much numerical and theoretical work has shown that the Ginzburg criterion is a good indicator of the appropriateness of a mean-field description ma ; bigklein . It is in this sense that we will use the Ginzburg criterion in the following.

Equation (58) implies that the Ginzburg parameter for the fully connected Ising model is given by G=Nϵ2G=N\epsilon^{2} (up to numerical factors). Mean-field theory for the fully connected Ising model becomes exact if the limit NN\rightarrow\infty is taken before ϵ0\epsilon\to 0 bigklein . As ϵ\epsilon decreases for fixed NN, GG decreases, which implies that the system becomes less describable by mean-field theory. To determine the critical exponents for the fully connected Ising model for a large but finite value of NN in a simulation, we need to keep the system at the same level of mean field, which implies that we must keep GG constant. Hence, as ϵ0\epsilon\to 0, we need to consider larger and larger values of NN. Keeping GG constant has the additional consequence of restoring two exponent scaling, which is missing in the standard treatments of mean-field systems tane ; lou .

Another conclusion that follows from the Ginzburg criterion is that the scaling of the isothermal susceptibility χ\chi must be the same as the scaling of ξdϕ2\xi^{d}\phi^{2} or Nϕ2N\phi^{2} in the fully connected Ising model, which justifies multiplying the square of the average of ϕ=ϵ1/2ψ\phi=\epsilon^{1/2}\psi by NN to obtain χ\chi.

Because we need to hold G=Nϵ2G=N\epsilon^{2} constant to find consistent results for the mean-field Ising exponents, the result that the mean energy per spin is proportional to 1/Nϵ1/N\epsilon can now be properly interpreted. We have

EN=1Nϵ=ϵNϵ2=ϵGϵ,\frac{\langle E\rangle}{N}=\frac{1}{N\epsilon}=\frac{\epsilon}{N\epsilon^{2}}=\frac{\epsilon}{G}\sim\epsilon, (59)

where we have assumed that GG is a constant. This result is what is expected from a mean-field calculation because the nonanalytic part of the mean energy per spin should scale as ϵ1α\epsilon^{1-\alpha}, with the mean-field value of the specific heat exponent α=0\alpha=0.

We next calculate the specific heat of the fully connected Ising model by recasting the Ginzburg criterion in terms of the energy fluctuations. For mean-field theory to be applicable, the fluctuations of the energy must be small compared to the square of the mean energy, or

ξdCξ2de2=CNϵ2=CGC,\frac{\xi^{d}C}{\xi^{2d}e^{2}}=\frac{C}{N\epsilon^{2}}=\frac{C}{G}\rightarrow C, (60)

where CC is the specific heat. As expected, holding GG constant implies that the specific heat exponent α=0\alpha=0. If we hold NN rather than GG constant, we would obtain 1α=11-\alpha=-1 and α=2\alpha=-2. We see that the two results for α\alpha are not consistent unless GG is held constant.

Note that the exponents β=1/2\beta=1/2 and γ=1\gamma=1 are the same whether we hold NN or GG constant, but the value of α\alpha depends on whether NN or GG is held constant. Also the scaling relation (2) cannot be satisfied for γ=1\gamma=1 and β=1/2\beta=1/2 unless α=0\alpha=0 which in turn implies that we need to keep GG constant (and large) to obtain a consistent mean-field description.

Also note that the form of the right-hand side of Eq. (57) is the same as the action or Hamiltonian that we derived for the GED model using the Parisi-Sourlas method with ϵ2\epsilon^{2} replaced by μ0(1λ)/f02\mu_{0}(1-\lambda)/f_{0}^{2} [see Eq. (42)].

Acknowledgements.
We thank Ole Peters, Jon Machta, Jan Tobochnik, Bruce Boghosian, and Alex Adamou for useful discussions. WK would like to acknowledge the hospitality of the London Mathematical Laboratory where part of this work was done.

References

  • (1) J. Angle, “Deriving the size distribution of personal wealth from ‘the rich get richer, the poor get poorer’,” J. Math. Sociol. 18, 27 (1993).
  • (2) S. Ispolatov, P. L. Krapivsky and S. Redner, “Wealth distributions in asset exchange models,” Eur. Phys. J. B 2, 267 (1998).
  • (3) A. Drãgulescu and V. M. Yakovenko, “Statistical mechanics of money,” Eur. Phys. J B 17, 723 (2000).
  • (4) J.-P. Bouchaud and M. Mézard, “Wealth condensation in a simple model of economy,” Physica A 282, 536 (2000).
  • (5) A. Chakraborti and B. K. Chakrabarti, “Statistical mechanics of money: how saving propensity affects its distribution,” Eur. Phys. J. B 17, 167 (2000).
  • (6) A. Chakraborti, “Distributions of money in model markets of economy,” Int J. Mod. Phys. C 13, 1315 (2002).
  • (7) B. Hayes, “Follow the money,” American Scientist 90, 400 (2002).
  • (8) Z. Burda, D. Johnston, J. Jurkiewicz, M. Kamiński, M. A. Nowak, G. Papp, and I. Zahed, “Wealth condensation in Pareto macroeconomies,” Phys. Rev. E 65, 026102 (2002).
  • (9) J. Angle, “The inequality process as a wealth maximizing process,” Physica 367, 388 (2006).
  • (10) P. L. Krapivsky and S. Redner, “Wealth distributions in asset exchange models,” Science and Culture 76, 424 (2010).
  • (11) B. K. Chakrabarti and A. Chakraborti, “Fifteen years of econophysics research,” Sci. Culture 76, 293 (2010).
  • (12) C. F. Moukarzel, S. Goncalves, J. R. Iglesias, M. Rodriguez-Achach, and R. Huerta-Quintanilla, “Wealth condensation in a multiplicative random asset exchange model,” Eur. Phys. J.-Spec. Top. 143, 75 (2007).
  • (13) V. M. Yakovenko and J. Barkley Rosser, Jr., “Colloquium: Statistical mechanics of money, wealth, and income,” Rev. Mod. Phys. 81, 1703 (2009).
  • (14) Bruce M. Boghosian, “The Inescapable Casino,” Scientific American 321, 70 (2019).
  • (15) B. M. Boghosian, “Kinetics of wealth and the Pareto law,” Phys. Rev. E 89, 042804 (2014).
  • (16) B. M. Boghosian, A. Devitt-Lee, M. Johnson, J. Li, J. A. Marcq, and H. Wang, “Oligarchy as a phase transition: The effect of wealth-attained advantage in a Fokker-Planck description of asset exchange,” Physica A 476, 15 (2017).
  • (17) A Devitt-Lee, H. Wang, J. Ii, and B. Boghosian, “A nonstandard description of wealth concentration in large-scale economies,” Siam J. Appl. Math 78, 996 (2018).
  • (18) J. Li, B. M. Boghosian, and C. Li, “The Affine Wealth Model: An agent-based model of asset exchange that allows for negative-wealth agents and its empirical validation,” Physica A 516, 423 (2019).
  • (19) C. Chorro, “A simple probabilistic approach of the Yard-Sale model,” Statistics and Probability Letters 112, 35 (2016).
  • (20) Kang K. L. Liu, N. Lubbers, W. Klein, J. Tobochnik, B. M. Boghosian, and H. Gould, “Simulation of a generalized asset exchange model with economic growth and wealth distribution,” arXiv:2102.01268.
  • (21) J. M. Yeomans, Statistical Mechanics of Phase Transitions, Clarendon Press (1972).
  • (22) S. K. Ma, Modern Theory of Critical Phenomena, Westview Press (2000).
  • (23) W. Klein and G. Batrouni, “Supersymmetry in spinodal decomposition and continuous ordering,’ Phys. Rev. Lett. 67, 1278 (1991).
  • (24) P. C. Hohenberg and B. I. Halperin, “Theory of dynamic critical phenomena,” Rev. Mod. Phys. 49, 435 (1977).
  • (25) G. Parisi and N. Sourlas, “Random magnetic fields, supersymmetry, and negative dimensions,” Phys. Rev. Lett. 43, 744 (1979).
  • (26) W. Klein, H. Gould, N. Gulbahce, J. B. Rundle, and K. Tiampo, “The structure of fluctuations near mean-field critical points and spinodals and its implication for physical processes,” Phys. Rev. E 75, 031114 (2007).
  • (27) L. Colonna-Romano, H. Gould and W. Klein, “Anomalous mean-field behavior of the fully connected Ising model,” Phys. Rev. E 90, 042111 (2014).
  • (28) M. Kac, G. E. Uhlenbeck, and P. C. Hemmer, “On the van der Waals theory of the vapor-liquid equilibrium. I. Discussion of a one-dimensional model,” J. Math. Phys. 4, 216 (1963).
  • (29) B.-H. F. Cardoso, S. Gonçalves, J. R. Iglesias, “Wealth distribution models with regulations: Dynamics and equilibria,” Physica A 551, 124201 (2020). The authors investigated a modification of the Yard-Sale model that favors the poorer agent (social protection). One consequence is that the agents in their model have economic mobility under certain conditions and the system reaches a steady state.
  • (30) O. Peters, “Optimal leverage from non-ergodicity,” Quant. Fin. 11, 1593 (2011).
  • (31) O. Peters and W. Klein, “Ergodicity breaking in geometric Brownian motion,” Phys. Rev. Lett. 110, 100603 (2013).
  • (32) J. B. Rundle, W. Klein, S. Gross and D. L. Turcotte, “Boltzmann fluctuations in numerical simulations of non-equilibrium threshold systems,” Phys. Rev. Lett. 75 1658 (1995).
  • (33) Kang K. L. Liu, J. B. Silva, W. Klein, and H. Gould, “Anomalous behavior of the specific heat in systems with long-range interactions,” manuscript in preparation. It is shown that holding the Ginzburg parameter constant is necessary for the probability distribution of the energy to have the Boltzmann form with the density of states having no explicit dependence on the temperature or the noise amplitude.
  • (34) O. Peters, “The ergodicity problem in economics,” Nature Physics 15, 1216 (2019).
  • (35) T. S. Ray and W. Klein, “Crossover and breakdown of hyperscaling in long range bond percolation,” J. Stat. Phys. 53, 773 (1988).