Influence of risk tolerance on long-term investments: A Malliavin calculus approach
Abstract
This study investigates the influence of risk tolerance on the expected utility in the long run. We estimate the extent to which the expected utility of optimal portfolios is affected by small changes in the risk tolerance. For this purpose, we adopt the Malliavin calculus method and the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition, through which the expected utility is expressed in terms of the eigenvalues and eigenfunctions of an operator. We conclude that the influence of risk aversion on the expected utility is determined by these eigenvalues and eigenfunctions in the long run.
1 Introduction
1.1 Overview
The risk–return trade-off is an important issue in finance. Investors assess returns against risk while considering investment strategies, and they choose strategies that maximize the returns while minimizing the risk. There are several ways to formulate the risk–return trade-off. One of the most commonly accepted forms is the utility function, which reflects the risk tolerance of an investor. We quantify the extent to which the expected utility is affected by small changes in the risk tolerance.
This study investigates long-term investment strategies.
Under several market models, utility-maximizing portfolios and their expected utility are considered.
For this purpose, we adopt the Malliavin calculus method and the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition, through which the expected utility is expressed in terms of
the eigenvalues and eigenfunctions
of an operator.
We conclude that the influence of risk tolerance on the long-term expected utility is determined by these eigenvalues and eigenfunctions.
The main objective of this study is to investigate the influence of small changes of the utility function on long-term investments. We recall the classical utility maximization problem
over all admissible self-financing portfolios with a given initial capital for terminal time The constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function
for is considered in this paper. The parameter represents how an investor measures his/her degree of risk tolerance. The optimal portfolio depends on the parameter thus
We investigate the influence of small changes in the parameter on the expected utility over a long time horizon. The influence of small changes in the parameter in terms of its logarithmic value can be mathematically expressed as
We estimate the large-time behavior of this partial derivative as
The main methodology for this analysis is a combination of the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition and the Malliavin calculus technique presented in Sections 2 and 3. This approach is from Park (2018). First, we transform the expected utility into the expectation form
for some Markov diffusion process with and some measurable function The process with killing rate induces an infinitesimal generator. Using the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition, we can find an eigenvalue and a positive eigenfunction of the generator as well as a measurable function such that the expectation is written as
The real number and the functions and depend on the parameter By differentiating with respect to we have
Using the above-mentioned equation, we estimate the influence of risk tolerance on the long-term expected utility. If is bounded in on then
for some positive constant This implies that the influence of risk tolerance is asymptotically equal to the partial derivative of with respect to which is the main conclusion of this study. The Malliavin calculus technique is used to verify that is bounded in on We cover several market models, namely the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process, the CIR process, the model, a quadratic drift model.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The related literature is reviewed in Section 1.2. The utility maximization problem, the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition and the Malliavin calculus method are explained as mathematical preliminaries in Section 2. The main ideas and arguments for investigating the influence of risk tolerance are discussed in Section 3. The influence of risk tolerance on utility-maximizing portfolios is illustrated in Section 4. Finally, our findings are summarized in Section 5. The technical details are presented in the appendices.
1.2 Related literature
Many authors have studied the stability of the optimal investment strategy with respect to the utility function. Jouini and Napp (2004) studied in a general complete financial market the stability of the optimal investment-consumption strategy with respect to the choice of the utility function. More precisely, for a given sequence of utility functions that converges pointwise, they proved the almost sure as well as the -convergence of the optimal wealth and consumption at each date. Carassus and Rásonyi (2007) investigated the convergence of optimal strategies with respect to a sequence of utility functions. They also established the continuity of the utility indifference price with respect to changes in agents’ preferences. Nutz (2012) considered the economic problem of optimal consumption and investment with power utility. As the relative risk aversion tends to infinity or to one was proved, the convergence of the optimal consumption is obtained for general semimartingale models while the convergence of the optimal trading strategy is obtained for continuous models.
The dependence of the risk tolerance on the investment strategy has been studied many authors. Zariphopoulou and Zhou (2009) analyzed a portfolio choice problem when the local risk tolerance is time-dependent and asymptotically linear in wealth. This methodology allows the investment performance to be measured in terms of the risk tolerance and alternative market views. Mocha and Westray (2013) studied the sensitivity of the power utility maximization problem with respect to the investor’s relative risk aversion, the statistical probability measure, the investment constraints, and the market price of risk. Paravisini et al. (2017) estimated risk tolerance from investors’ financial decisions in a person-to-person lending platform. They developed a method that obtains a risk-tolerance parameter from each portfolio choice on the basis of the elasticity of risk tolerance to changes in wealth. Bi and Cai (2019) investigated the optimal investment–reinsurance strategies for an agent with state-dependent risk tolerance and value-at-risk constraints. They derived the closed-form expressions of the optimal strategies and discussed the impact of the risk tolerance. Delong (2019) considered agents whose risk tolerance consists of a constant risk tolerance and a small wealth-dependent risk tolerance. He investigated an exponential utility maximization problem for an agent who faces a stream of non-hedgeable claims.
Numerous studies have investigated the topic of long-term investment strategies. Fleming and Sheu (2000) considered an optimal investment model to maximize the long-term growth rate of the expected utility of wealth. The problem was reformulated as a risk‐sensitive control problem with an infinite time horizon. Hansen and Scheinkman (2009), Hansen (2012) and Hansen and Scheinkman (2012) exploited the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition method and demonstrated a long-term risk–return trade-off. Guasoni and Robertson (2015) studied a class of static fund separation theorems that is valid for investors with a long time horizon and constant relative risk tolerance. Robertson and Xing (2015) investigated long-term portfolio choice problems by analyzing the large-time asymptotic behavior of solutions to semi-linear Cauchy problems.
Malliavin calculus has been studied in relation to various topics in quantitative finance. Fournié et al. (1999) investigated a probabilistic method for computations of Greeks in finance. This methodology is based on the integration-by-parts formula developed in Malliavin calculus. Benhamou (2003) showed that the Malliavin weight functions for Greeks must satisfy necessary and sufficient conditions expressed as conditional expectations. Alos et al. (2007) used Malliavin calculus techniques to obtain an expression for the short-time behavior of the at-the-money implied volatility skew for a generalization of the Bates model, where the volatility does not need to be a diffusion or a Markov process. Borovička et al. (2014) studied the shock elasticity, which reflects the sensitivity with respect to a perturbation over a time instant. They proposed a Malliavin calculus method to compute the shock elasticity. Alòs and Shiraya (2019) studied the difference between the fair strike of a volatility swap and the at-the-money implied volatility of a European call option. They used the Malliavin calculus approach to derive an exact expression for this difference. Park and Sturm (2019) employed the Malliavin calculus method to investigate the sensitivities of the long-term expected utility of optimal portfolios under incomplete markets.
As a closely related article, Park (2018) conducted a sensitivity analysis of long-term cash flows. However, the perturbation form is different from this paper. He studied the extent to which the price of the cash flow is affected by small perturbations of the underlying Markov diffusion. He considered the drift and volatility perturbations in the underlying process
for the perturbation parameter , and analyzed their influence to the cash flows. This paper, however, works with the investor’s risk tolerance and the perturbations in the underlying process is not considered.
2 Mathematical preliminary
In this section, we demonstrate the utility maximization problem and the two main methodologies exploited in the rest of this study: the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition and the Malliavin calculus method.
2.1 Utility maximization problem
We consider the classical utility maximization problem in financial markets. Let be a filtered probability space having a one-dimensional Brownian motion and a -dimensional Brownian motion with constant correlation The measure is referred to as the physical measure and the filtration is the argumentation of the natural filtration of and We assume that the market has a state process which is a Markov diffusion satisfying
(2.1) |
There are assets in the market, where is a risk-free asset and are risky assets. The assets dynamics are given as
(2.2) | ||||
Here, is the short interest rate function, is the excess return function, and is the volatility matrix functions.
A portfolio is a -dimensional process , which represents the proportions of wealth in each risky asset. The wealth process of with positive initial capital satisfies
(2.3) |
We assume that the portfolio process is -adapted and the integrations in Eq.(2.3) are well-defined, that is, for all where is the usual Euclidean norm. The wealth process for all a.s. since the initial wealth
In this market, we consider an agent who wants to maximize the expected utility of the terminal wealth over all possible portfolios. More precisely, we are interested in
over all possible portfolios for given positive initial capital The utility function is assumed to be a power function of the form
(2.4) |
for
This utility maximization problem can be solved by using stochastic control theory. Define the value function as
Following (Zariphopoulou, 2001, Proposition 2.1), we have
where and the -dynamics of is
(2.5) |
with a -Brownian motion For it follows that
for
(2.6) |
Here, we have used the notation In particular, when the short rate is a constant
(2.7) |
where
(2.8) |
and
2.2 Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition
We briefly review the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition as a mathematical preliminary. Readers may refer to Hansen and Scheinkman (2009), Park (2018), and Qin and Linetsky (2016) for further details. Consider a filtered probability space having a -dimensional Brownian motion The family is the completed filtration generated by
We begin with the state space and four functions Let be an open and connected subset of and let and be continuously differentiable functions. The matrix is invertible. The function is continuous and the function is nonnegative continuously differentiable. For each assume that the SDE Eq.(2.1) has a unique strong solution on
We can consider an infinitesimal generator and its eigenpair. Define the infinitesimal generator of the process with killing rate as
(2.9) |
where For a real number and a positive -function we say that a pair is an eigenpair of if
(2.10) |
For by applying the Ito formula, we can show that for each eigenpair a positive process
(2.11) |
is a local martingale. Assume that this process is a martingale. We can define a measure on each for by
The family is consistent, i.e., for all For fixed we use the notation instead of suppressing This measure on is called the eigen-measure with respect to The process
is a -Brownian motion by the Girsanov theorem, and the process satisfies
Under these circumstances, consider the decomposition of the discount factor
(2.12) |
which comes from Eq.(2.11). This expression is called the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. The expectation can be written as
(2.13) | ||||
where for and The function is referred to as the remainder function. The decomposition in Eq.(2.13) is useful for the analysis of because the expectation depends on the final random variable whereas the expression
depends on the entire path of If we know the -distribution of , then we can analyze the expectation directly. For notational simplicity, when the eigenpair is specified, we use the notations , and instead of , and respectively, suppressing
We summarize this section in the following proposition.
Proposition 2.1.
Let be an open and connected subset of Assume the following conditions.
-
(i)
The functions and are continuously differentiable functions, and the matrix is invertible. The function is continuous.
-
(ii)
For each the SDE (2.1) has a unique strong solution on
If is an eigenpair of the operator in Eq.(2.9), then the process in Eq.(2.11) is a local martingale. If this process is a martingale, then
where is the eigen-measure with respect to
2.3 Malliavin calculus
This section presents a brief review of Malliavin calculus. For further details, refer to Malliavin and Paul (2006) and Nualart and Nualart (2018). Let be a filtered probability space having a one-dimensional Brownian motion The filtration is the natural filtration of Define the set of all cylindrical random variables as
where is the set of all functions such that and all its partial derivatives have polynomial growth. The Malliavin derivative of is defined as a stochastic process given by
Then, is a linear operator from to and it is known that is closable. The closure is also denoted as The domain of is the closure of under the norm
and is denoted as
We will use the following propositions. Propositions 2.2, 2.3, and 2.5 are from (León et al., 2003, Lemma 2.1), (Protter, 2004, Theorem 39 on page 312), and (Park, 2018, Proposition A.1), respectively.
Proposition 2.2.
Let be a continuously differentiable function and Then, if and only if and and in this case,
Proposition 2.3.
Let be a Markov diffusion whose dynamics is given as
with initial value , where and are continuously differentiable functions with bounded derivatives. Then, the map is continuously differentiable almost surely and the derivative process satisfies
equivalently,
Moreover, for each and its Malliavin derivative satisfies
Proposition 2.4.
(Integration by parts formula) Let and be a progressively measurable process with Then
Proposition 2.5.
Let be continuously differentiable functions with and let be a continuous function on an open interval Define for , where is an open neighborhood of Assume that the SDE
has a unique strong solution on for all and Suppose that for , there exist positive constants with and such that
(2.14) | |||
(2.15) | |||
(2.16) |
Then, the expectation is continuously differentiable in and
(2.17) |
where
3 Main arguments
This study investigates the influence of risk tolerance on the optimal expected utility in the long run.
It involves the following steps.
Step I. Transform the expected utility from the optimal investment strategy into the expectation form
where the -dynamics of is
The drift function
and the killing rate may depend on
however, the volatility function does not depend on This step was conducted in Section 2.1.
Step II. Through the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition discussed in Section 2.2, the expectation can be expressed as
where is an eigenpair and The -dynamics of is
where It follows that
(3.1) |
In the remainder function observe that the drift function the eigenfunction , and the measure depend on For convenience, define Then,
This is the key observation of this study. The perturbation of the risk aversion is transformed into perturbations of the drift function, payoff function, and eigenfunction.
Step III. We prove (case by case for each model) that the term is bounded in on This is achieved as follows. First, show that the denominator converges to a positive constant as More precisely, the process has an invariant distribution under the measure and the remainder function
as with Second, show that
is bounded in on This can be easily checked by direct calculation; thus, we do not go into further detail here.
Finally, show that
is bounded in on Observe that the perturbation parameter is only in the drift term of the dynamics of We adopt the Malliavin calculus method to estimate this partial derivative. Assume that the map is continuously differentiable for each and denote the first-order approximation as i.e.,
as Under suitable conditions (Propositions 2.2, 2.3, and 2.5),
(3.2) | ||||
where is the first variation process of
For all the models in Section 4, this probabilistic representation will be used to show that the partial derivative is bounded in on
Step IV. Since is bounded in on in Eq.(3.1), we finally obtain
for some positive constant In particular,
This implies that the influence of the risk tolerance parameter on long-term investments is determined by the eigenvalue of the generator of the underlying Markov diffusion.
4 Utility-maximizing portfolios
We cover several models, namely the Black–Scholes model, the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck (OU) process, the Cox–Ingersoll–Ross (CIR) model, the model, and a quadratic drift model. Throughout this section, we assume the short rate is a constant (and thus, in Eq.(2.8) will be used).
4.1 Black–Scholes model
As a motivating example, consider a constant proportion portfolio when the underlying market follows the Black–Scholes model. Assume that the short rate is a constant and the stock price follows
for With the initial capital it is known that the optimal expected utility is
(4.1) |
We aim to investigate the influence of the risk aversion on the long-term investment. We calculate the partial derivative
The partial derivative grows linearly as and the linear growth rate is
4.2 OU process
Under the physical measure let the state process follow the OU process
(4.2) |
for , and assume that and for some constant (this holds, for example, and the state process is the market price of risk). Then, the -dynamics of given in Eq.(2.5) is
(4.3) |
and , where and
We now apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition stated in Section 2.2. Eq.(A.3) gives
(4.4) |
where , and
(4.5) |
is the remainder function. Under the measure the process satisfies
for It follows that
(4.6) |
It suffices to investigate the term since the other terms on the right-hand side of Eq.(4.6) are easy to estimate. Since only the parameters and depend on in the remainder function , using the chain rule, we know that
By Proposition A.1, the function converges to a positive constant as , and four partial derivatives are bounded in Therefore,
for some positive constant By using Eq.(2.7), we finally conclude that
for some positive constant and
(4.7) | ||||
which is obtained by direct calculation.
Remark 4.1.
The optimal expected utility has explicit solutions when the market price of risk is an affine model such as the OU process or the CIR model. However, is extremely complicated and challenging to calculate from the explicit solutions. In this study, we adopt the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition and Malliavin calculus so that it is much simpler to calculate the long-term sensitivity using our approach rather than using the explicit solutions.
4.3 CIR model
Under the physical measure let the state process follow the CIR model
(4.8) |
for and assume that and for some constant (this holds, for example, and the market price of risk is the square root of the state process). Then, the -dynamics of given in Eq.(2.5) is
(4.9) |
and , where and
We now apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. Eq.(B.4) gives
(4.10) |
where , and is the remainder function. The -dynamics of is
It follows that
(4.11) |
It suffices to investigate the term since the other terms on the right-hand side of the above-mentioned equality are easy to estimate. Since only the parameters and depend on in the remainder function, using the chain rule, we know that
By Proposition B.1, the function converges to a positive constant as , and two partial derivatives and are bounded in Therefore,
for some positive constant By using Eq.(2.7), we finally conclude that
for some positive constant and
which is obtained by direct calculation.
4.4 model
Under the physical measure let the state process follow the model
(4.12) |
for and assume that and for some constant (this holds, for example, and the market price of risk is the square root of the state process). Then, the -dynamics of given in Eq.(2.5) is
(4.13) |
and , where and
We now apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. Eq.(C.4) gives
(4.14) |
where , and is the remainder function. The -dynamics of is
(4.15) |
for It follows that
(4.16) |
It suffices to investigate the term since the other terms on the right-hand side of the above-mentioned equality are easy to estimate. Since only the parameters and depend on in the remainder function, using the chain rule, we know that
The function converges to a positive constant as and two partial derivatives and are bounded in by Proposition C.1. Therefore,
for some positive constant By using Eq.(2.7), we finally conclude that
for some positive constant and
(4.17) | ||||
4.5 Quadratic drift model
Under the physical measure let the state process follow a quadratic drift model
(4.18) |
for and assume that and for some constant (this holds, for example, and the state process is the market price of risk). There is a unique strong solution to the above SDE (Carr and Willems, 2019, Proposition 2.1). Then, under the measure the process satisfies
(4.19) |
and , where and
We now apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. Eq.(D.2) gives
(4.20) |
where , and is the remainder function. The -dynamics of is
(4.21) |
It follows that
(4.22) |
It suffices to investigate the term since the other terms on the right-hand side of the above-mentioned equality are easy to estimate. Since only the parameters and depend on in the remainder function, using the chain rule, we know that
The function converges to a positive constant as and two partial derivatives and are bounded in by Proposition D.1. Therefore,
for some positive constant By using Eq.(2.7), we finally conclude that
for some positive constant and
(4.23) | ||||
Figure 1 displays comparative analysis between the four models. Two graphs show the partial derivative as a function of and respectively. The model parameters are given as (for the first graph), (for the second graph) and


5 Conclusion
This study investigated the influence of risk tolerance on the expected utility in the long run. We focused on the power utility function of the form
for , where the parameter represents how an investor measures the degree of his/her risk tolerance. We considered utility-maximizing portfolios and demonstrated the influence of small changes in the parameter on the expected utility of the portfolios in the long run.
The main methodology for this analysis involved a combination of the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition and the Malliavin calculus technique. First, we transformed the expected utility into the expectation form
for some Markov diffusion process with and some measurable functions and Using the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition, the expectation was written as
for a real number a positive function , and a measurable function which depend on the parameter
The influence of risk tolerance on the long-term expected utility was obtained from the above-mentioned Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. Under the condition that is bounded in on we showed that
for some positive constant
The influence of risk tolerance
is asymptotically equal to the partial derivative of with respect to which is the main conclusion of this study.
To verify that
is bounded in on the Malliavin calculus method was used under
several market models, namely the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process, the CIR process, the model, and a quadratic drift model.
Acknowledgments.
Hyungbin Park was supported by the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF) grants funded by the Ministry of Science and ICT (No. 2017R1A5A1015626, No. 2018R1C1B5085491 and No. 2021R1C1C1011675)
and the Ministry of Education (No. 2019R1A6A1A10073437) through the Basic Science Research Program.
Appendix A OU process with quadratic killing rate
Assume that a process satisfies
(A.1) |
where For consider the expectation
The corresponding operator is
and it can be shown that
is an eigenpair, where
The eigen-measure is defined on as
(A.2) |
The expectation can be expressed as
(A.3) | ||||
where
(A.4) |
is the remainder function. The process
is a -Brownian motion and follows
for
We study the large-time asymptotic behavior of the sensitivity of the remainder function
Proposition A.1.
Suppose that follows
(A.5) |
for and Define
for and Then,
(A.6) |
as , where is the invariant distribution of The partial derivatives and are bounded in on
Proof.
Observe that the density function of with is
where is the mean and is the variance. Then, it is clear that
as , where
This proves Eq.(A.6).
We now show that is bounded in on This is direct from
(A.7) | ||||
since the limit is a finite number. Using the same method, we can show that is bounded in on
We show that is bounded in on Define for notational simplicity. By Propositions 2.2, 2.4, and 2.5, we have
(A.8) | ||||
Considering that the Malliavin derivative of is for we have
(A.9) |
Choose such that and such that Then,
Using and the density function of it is easy to check that and are bounded in and respectively. This gives the desired result. Using the same method, we can show that is bounded in on ∎
Appendix B CIR model
Let be the CIR model given as
(B.1) |
where and For
(B.2) |
consider the expectation
The corresponding operator is
Following Qin and Linetsky (2016), we know that
is an eigenpair of this operator, where
The eigen-measure is defined on as
(B.3) |
It is easy to check that a local martingale is a martingale. The expectation can be expressed as
(B.4) |
where
(B.5) |
is the remainder function. Note that the expectation by Lemma B.2 because The process
is a -Brownian motion and follows
We study the large-time asymptotic behavior of the remainder function and its sensitivity with respect to the parameters and
Proposition B.1.
Suppose that follows
(B.6) |
for and Define
for Then,
(B.7) |
as , where is the invariant distribution of The partial derivatives and are bounded in on
Proof.
It is easy to prove Eq.(B.7) by considering the density function of thus, we omit the proof. Consider the partial derivative Choose any with then there is a positive constant such that for Observe that
thus,
By Lemma B.2, the expectation is bounded in on , and this gives the desired result.
Now, we show that the partial derivative is bounded in on Define for notational simplicity. By Propositions 2.2, 2.4, and 2.5, we have
(B.8) | ||||
The last equality is from
which is obtained by for the first variation process of This can be obtained from the work of Alòs and Ewald (2008) (note that Proposition 2.3 cannot be applied here because the coefficients in Eq.(B.6) do not have bounded derivatives). Then,
(B.9) | ||||
Since and by Lemma B.2, the expectation is bounded in on It is clear that is bounded in on Thus,
(B.10) |
for some positive constant which gives the desired result. ∎
Lemma B.2.
Let be a solution of
where and For , we have
where
Proof.
See Corollary 6.3.4.4 in Jeanblanc et al. (2009), where the proof is given for ; the same proof holds for ∎
Appendix C model
Consider the model
where , and For
(C.1) |
define
Then, it is easy to check that
We apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition to estimate the expectation
The corresponding operator is
and it can be shown that is an eigenpair. The eigen-measure is defined on as
(C.2) |
The process
is a Brownian motion by the Girsanov theorem, and follows
(C.3) |
for
The expectation can be expressed as
(C.4) |
where
(C.5) |
is the remainder function. Considering that is a CIR model and has linear growth, the function converges to a constant as
We study the large-time asymptotic behavior of the remainder function and its sensitivity with respect to the parameters and
Proposition C.1.
Suppose that follows
(C.6) |
for Define
for Then,
(C.7) |
as , where is the invariant distribution of The partial derivatives and are bounded in on
Proof.
It is easy to prove Eq.(C.7) by considering the density function of We prove that two partial derivatives and are bounded in on First, consider the partial derivative Observe that
There are constants , and such that
and
Thus, by Lemma C.2, the partial derivative is bounded in on
Now we show that the partial derivative is bounded in on Define for notational simplicity. By Propositions 2.2, 2.4, and 2.5, we have
(C.8) | ||||
For the last equality, we used that the Malliavin derivative of is
(C.9) |
From
(C.10) |
we have
(C.11) | ||||
where is defined as
(C.12) | ||||
The second equality is from the Markov property.
We aim to estimate this function Define a measure on as
It is easy to show that a local martingale is a martingale. The process satisfies
where is a -Brownian motion. Note that since the mean-reversion speed the process stays positive under the measure It follows that
We apply the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition here. Consider the operator
It can be shown that is an eigenpair, and let be the corresponding eigen-measure. The -dynamics of is
where is a -Brownian motion. Then,
Since and holds, by Lemma C.2 (with replaced by ), the expectation is uniformly bounded in on Thus,
for some positive constant which is independent of and Eq.(C.11) gives
(C.13) |
By Lemma C.2, the expectation is bounded in on This gives the desired result. ∎
Lemma C.2.
Let be a solution of
for , and Then, for
(C.14) |
where is the confluent hypergeometric function. The function converges to
as Moreover, if then the function is uniformly bounded on the domain
See (Park, 2019, Lemma B.1) for the proof.
Appendix D Quadratic drift model
Assume that follows
(D.1) |
for This SDE has a unique strong solution and the solution stays positive by (Carr and Willems, 2019, Proposition 2.1). For we define
Consider the generator
It can be shown that is an eigenpair, where
Let be the eigen-measure on defined as
Then, the -dynamics of is
for a -Brownian motion It can be easily checked that the local martingale is a martingale. It follows that
(D.2) |
where
The invariant measure of under the measure is
up to positive constant multiples. For further details on the invariant measure, readers may refer to (Löcherbach, 2015, Proposition 3.2) or (Kallenberg, 2006, Lemma 20.19).
Proposition D.1.
Suppose that follows
(D.3) |
for Define
for Then,
(D.4) |
as , where is the invariant distribution of The partial derivatives and are bounded in on
Proof.
Since by Proposition (D.2), we have Eq.(D.4). By the same method in Eq.(A.7), it follows that is bounded in We now show that the partial derivative is bounded in on Define for notational simplicity. We have
(D.5) | ||||
By Proposition D.3, the Malliavin derivative of is
The last inequality is from Thus,
(D.6) | ||||
Choose constants and such that and Then,
(D.7) |
Observe that since By Proposition D.2, the expectation converges to as In particular, the expectation is bounded in on Similarly, the expectation is also bounded in on Since the right-hand side of Eq.(D.7) is bounded in on we obtain the desired result. ∎
Proposition D.2.
Let Then,
as
Proof.
Consider the eigenvalue–eigenfunction problem of the second-order differential operator
densely defined on the space We first show that the spectral gap is positive. By (Fulton et al., 2005, Theorem 12 (ii)), is bounded below since is non-oscillatory. By (Fulton et al., 2005, Theorem 14), it suffices to show that the essential spectrum is empty. We can write the equation in the divergence form as
(D.8) |
where
Using the Liouville transformation (for example, (Everitt, 2005, Section 7)), Eq.(D.8) becomes
where
and By direct calculation, as more precisely, exists and is a positive constant. In particular, as , and this implies that the essential spectrum is empty from (Ćurgus and Read, 2002, Corollary 4.2). Finally, since the spectral gap is positive, by (Qin and Linetsky, 2016, Theorem 5.2 (iii)), we have
for This completes the proof. ∎
Proposition D.3.
Let be the solution of
Then, for the random variable is in , and the Malliavin derivative is
for
Proof.
Choose such that for all Let be the solution of the SDE
This SDE has a unique strong solution since the coefficients are Lipschitz, and the solution stays positive by (Zhao, 2009, Eq.(0.2)). For let be a continuously differentiable function satisfying
(D.9) |
as well as for all Since is a Lipschitz function, the SDE
(D.10) |
has a unique strong solution By the comparison theorem (for example, see (Karatzas and Shreve, 1991, Proposition 2.18 in Chapter 5)), we know that a.s.
Since the Malliavin derivative is a closed operator, it suffices to show that in as and in as We prove these in the following two stops. The first step is to show that the random variable in as We use the dominated convergence theorem to prove this. For each define a stopping time Then, it is clear that is nondecreasing and a.s. Let denote the stopped process of at . Then, we have
from the definition of Letting it follows that a.s. Observe that and by (Zhao, 2009, Corollay 2.2). The dominated convergence theorem implies that as
The second step is to show that
as Since the coefficients of SDE (D.10) are continuously differentiable with bounded derivatives, the solution for each and
by (Fournié et al., 1999, Property P2). Observe that a.s. for each and for all as Thus,
We claim that this convergence also holds in By the dominated convergence theorem, it suffices to find a -dominating function. Considering that for we have
(D.11) | ||||
and similarly, Thus,
(D.12) | ||||
The random variable is an -dominating function since
by (Zhao, 2009, Proposition 2.1). This completes the proof. ∎
References
- Alòs and Ewald (2008) Alòs, E. and Ewald, C.-O. (2008). Malliavin differentiability of the Heston volatility and applications to option pricing. Advances in Applied Probability, 40(1):144–162.
- Alos et al. (2007) Alos, E., León, J. A., and Vives, J. (2007). On the short-time behavior of the implied volatility for jump-diffusion models with stochastic volatility. Finance and Stochastics, 11(4):571–589.
- Alòs and Shiraya (2019) Alòs, E. and Shiraya, K. (2019). Estimating the Hurst parameter from short term volatility swaps: a Malliavin calculus approach. Finance and Stochastics, 23(2):423–447.
- Benhamou (2003) Benhamou, E. (2003). Optimal Malliavin weighting function for the computation of the Greeks. Mathematical Finance, 13(1):37–53.
- Bi and Cai (2019) Bi, J. and Cai, J. (2019). Optimal investment-reinsurance strategies with state dependent risk aversion and VaR constraints in correlated markets. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 85:1–14.
- Borovička et al. (2014) Borovička, J., Hansen, L. P., and Scheinkman, J. A. (2014). Shock elasticities and impulse responses. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 8(4):333–354.
- Carassus and Rásonyi (2007) Carassus, L. and Rásonyi, M. (2007). Optimal strategies and utility-based prices converge when agents’ preferences do. Mathematics of Operations Research, 32(1):102–117.
- Carr and Willems (2019) Carr, P. and Willems, S. (2019). A lognormal type stochastic volatility model with quadratic drift. Available at SSRN 3421304.
- Ćurgus and Read (2002) Ćurgus, B. and Read, T. T. (2002). Discreteness of the spectrum of second-order differential operators and associated embedding theorems. Journal of Differential Equations, 184(2):526–548.
- Delong (2019) Delong, Ł. (2019). Optimal investment for insurance company with exponential utility and wealth-dependent risk aversion coefficient. Mathematical Methods of Operations Research, 89(1):73–113.
- Everitt (2005) Everitt, W. N. (2005). A catalogue of Sturm–Liouville differential equations. In Sturm-Liouville Theory, pages 271–331. Springer.
- Fleming and Sheu (2000) Fleming, W. H. and Sheu, S. (2000). Risk-sensitive control and an optimal investment model. Mathematical Finance, 10(2):197–213.
- Fournié et al. (1999) Fournié, E., Lasry, J.-M., Lebuchoux, J., Lions, P.-L., and Touzi, N. (1999). Applications of Malliavin calculus to Monte Carlo methods in finance. Finance and Stochastics, 3(4):391–412.
- Fulton et al. (2005) Fulton, C., Pruess, S., and Xie, Y. (2005). The automatic classification of Sturm-Liouville problems. J. Appl. Math. Comput, 124:149–186.
- Guasoni and Robertson (2015) Guasoni, P. and Robertson, S. (2015). Static fund separation of long-term investments. Mathematical Finance, 25(4):789–826.
- Hansen (2012) Hansen, L. P. (2012). Dynamic valuation decomposition within stochastic economies. Econometrica, 80(3):911–967.
- Hansen and Scheinkman (2009) Hansen, L. P. and Scheinkman, J. (2009). Long-term risk: An operator approach. Econometrica, 77(1):177–234.
- Hansen and Scheinkman (2012) Hansen, L. P. and Scheinkman, J. (2012). Pricing growth-rate risk. Finance and Stochastics, 16(1):1–15.
- Jeanblanc et al. (2009) Jeanblanc, M., Yor, M., and Chesney, M. (2009). Mathematical methods for financial markets. Springer Science & Business Media.
- Jouini and Napp (2004) Jouini, E. and Napp, C. (2004). Convergence of utility functions and convergence of optimal strategies. Finance and Stochastics, 8(1):133–144.
- Kallenberg (2006) Kallenberg, O. (2006). Foundations of modern probability. Springer Science & Business Media.
- Karatzas and Shreve (1991) Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S. (1991). Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, volume 113. Springer Science & Business Media.
- León et al. (2003) León, J. A., Navarro, R., and Nualart, D. (2003). An anticipating calculus approach to the utility maximization of an insider. Mathematical Finance: An International Journal of Mathematics, Statistics and Financial Economics, 13(1):171–185.
- Löcherbach (2015) Löcherbach, E. (2015). Ergodicity and speed of convergence to equilibrium for diffusion processes.
- Malliavin and Paul (2006) Malliavin, T. and Paul, A. (2006). Stochastic calculus of variations in mathematical finance. Springer.
- Mocha and Westray (2013) Mocha, M. and Westray, N. (2013). The stability of the constrained utility maximization problem: a BSDE approach. SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 4(1):117–150.
- Nualart and Nualart (2018) Nualart, D. and Nualart, E. (2018). Introduction to Malliavin calculus, volume 9. Cambridge University Press.
- Nutz (2012) Nutz, M. (2012). Risk aversion asymptotics for power utility maximization. Probability Theory and Related Fields, 152(3-4):703–749.
- Paravisini et al. (2017) Paravisini, D., Rappoport, V., and Ravina, E. (2017). Risk aversion and wealth: Evidence from person-to-person lending portfolios. Management Science, 63(2):279–297.
- Park (2018) Park, H. (2018). Sensitivity analysis of long-term cash flows. Finance and Stochastics, 22(4):773–825.
- Park (2019) Park, H. (2019). Convergence rates of large-time sensitivities with the Hansen–Scheinkman decomposition. arXiv preprint arXiv:1912.03404.
- Park and Sturm (2019) Park, H. and Sturm, S. (2019). A sensitivity analysis of the long-term expected utility of optimal portfolios. Available at SSRN 3401532.
- Protter (2004) Protter, P. E. (2004). Stochastic integration and stochastic differential equations. Springer, Berlin.
- Qin and Linetsky (2016) Qin, L. and Linetsky, V. (2016). Positive eigenfunctions of Markovian pricing operators: Hansen-Scheinkman factorization, Ross recovery, and long-term pricing. Operations Research, 64(1):99–117.
- Robertson and Xing (2015) Robertson, S. and Xing, H. (2015). Large time behavior of solutions to semilinear equations with quadratic growth in the gradient. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 53(1):185–212.
- Zariphopoulou (2001) Zariphopoulou, T. (2001). A solution approach to valuation with unhedgeable risks. Finance and stochastics, 5(1):61–82.
- Zariphopoulou and Zhou (2009) Zariphopoulou, T. and Zhou, T. (2009). Investment performance measurement under asymptotically linear local risk tolerance. In Handbook of numerical analysis, volume 15, pages 227–253. Elsevier.
- Zhao (2009) Zhao, B. (2009). Inhomogeneous geometric Brownian motion. Available at SSRN 1429449.