Government intervention modeling in microeconomic company market evolution
Modern technology and innovations are becoming more crucial than ever for the survival of companies in the market. Therefore, it is significant both from theoretical and practical points of view to understand how governments can influence technology growth and innovation diffusion (TGID) processes. We propose a simple but essential extension of Ausloos-Clippe-Pȩkalski and related Cichy numerical models of the TGID in the market. Both models are inspired by the nonlinear non-equilibrium statistical physics. Our extension involves a parameter describing the probability of government intervention in the TGID process in the company market. We show, using Monte Carlo simulations, the effects interventionism can have on the companies’ market, depending on the segment of firms that are supported. The high intervention probability can result, paradoxically, in the destabilization of the market development. It lowers the market’s technology level in the long-time limit compared to markets with a lower intervention parameter. We found that the intervention in the technologically weak and strong segments of the company market does not substantially influence the market dynamics, compared to the intervention helping the middle-level companies. However, this is still a simple model which can be extended further and made more realistic by including other factors. Namely, the cost and risk of innovation or limited government resources and capabilities to support companies.
PACS number: 89.65.Gh, 02.50.–r, 05.10.Ln
keywords: government interventionism, Monte Carlo simulation, technology growth, econophysics
1 Introduction
New technologies have a tremendous impact on our economy. Ongoing globalization opened a new space for competition between firms all over the world, and it fuels the race for the most innovative technologies. Nowadays, the most technologically advanced firm is often the winner. The new technologies change how particular firms operate and perform, so it is interesting to study how technology can influence the market as a whole. This impact can not be underestimated, and it is no surprise that physicists are also interested in this many-body problem. A non-linear statistical physics simulated model for technological growth was recently proposed by Ausloos, Clippe, and Pȩkalski (ACP model) [2] and next extended by Cichy [3] (Ci-model).
Our work is directly inspired by Ci-model. It describes the influence of technology diffusion on market growth dynamics. The central assumption is that the companies’ survival depends only on their technology level. It might be a simplistic assumption; nonetheless, the results agree with the empirical data [3]. Therefore, we also make this assumption. However, we expand the model to make it more general, versatile, and realistic by taking into account the interventionism.
The companies operate in certain countries, and these countries’ politics influence the way those firms operate. The government and its policy can change the firms’ behavior, and those changes should be visible on the aggregate level as well. We propose a model that expands the existing technological growth model [3] to allow for modeling the influence of government intervention on company market growth. We do so by using a single parameter , which is the probability of the government intervention in case of a firm’s incoming bankruptcy. In practice, the intervention can be realized by government stimuli such as, for example, subsidies, grants, tax reliefs, taking over the company’s majority stake, and ultimately even by nationalizing the company. We also consider how the influence of this intervention differs when the government targets only specific segments of the company market.
2 Method
2.1 Model
We define the model as follows. In the beginning, a two-dimensional rectangular lattice of size is created ( in our case for simplicity). It is then occupied with pairs of numbers that represent the states of firms in the market. Two numbers describe each firm (e.g., the th): (i) its market share and (ii) its technology level – the latter is initially a random number between 0 and 1 drawn from a uniform distribution. The initial lattice density was chosen to be , which means that percent of the lattice sites are occupied with firms at the beginning of the simulation. Other lattice sites are empty. For example, we chose (the same as in [3]) as a representative for the higher concentration case. We plan to take into account other concentrations in future work. We decided to consider the higher concentration case () as it is more promising than the dilute case () in respect to a possible dynamical phase transition.
The market shares of all the companies have to sum up to 1 at any moment according to the normalization condition,
(1) |
Initially all of the companies have equal shares , where is the number of firms at a given time (Monte Carlo step/site defined further in the text) .
In every time-step, the system is characterized by some average technology level weighted by companies’ shares,
(2) |
with the initial condition, e.g. . This seems to be optimal in relation to the initial condition of world frontier dynamics given by Eq. (3) below.
As in paper [3], the companies in the market can benefit from copying the world frontier whose technology is described by
(3) |
where is the parameter measuring the world technological progress rate. In this model, the growth of the world’s technological advancement is defined by Moore’s law of exponential growth [7]. In our model we assume (as the most general case) that initially . We found a particularly interesting phase appearing at the transition time , which we define as the first time-step for which the inequality is fulfilled. We find numerically by calculating averaged additionally over time-dependent statistical ensemble of simulations (or replics of system). We show how the value of depends on the probability of government intervention . The changes in the market evolution that come right after are an essential aspect of our model that has both theoretical and practical meaning.
We note that the model parameters such as the current number of companies operating on the market , the shares of individual companies in the market , the world technological frontier progress rate (e.g., of the European Union) , and even the likelihood of mergers of companies can be obtained from empirical data. The analogue of inverse market temperature , (auxilliary) concentration , and the minimal number of companies needed for the market to work are free parameters of the model that can be obtained by matching the relative level of technology with empirical data. Let us add that the average level of market technology , as well as the current technology level of the world leader , can be measured separately (although it is complicated because it depends on the definition of technology level) [4]. As one can see, our model is prepared both for the analysis of empirical data and extension and generalization – it is a fully open model.
2.2 Algorithm
In this paper, we extend the Ci-model [3] substantially. This extension is important because it takes into account government interventionism supporting failing companies. This interventionism is described in the model by the probability , which we simply refer to as the parameter of government interventionism. A detailed description of the extended Ci-algorithm is presented below.
As usual, in the Monte Carlo simulations, we consider two time scales. The first is the Monte Carlo step (MCS or ) in which one cycle of the algorithm is carried out for a selected, single company. The second scale is a Monte Carlo step per lattice site (MCS/site or time step ). We define it as such a number of MCSs, which is equal to the number of sites of the substrate lattice.
Our algorithm is as follows:
-
1.
Randomly pick a single company from already existing firms by using a uniform distribution. Let it have index .
-
2.
Calculate the probability of the firm’s survival (defined by Eq. (8)).
-
3.
Compare value with a random number from a uniform distribution . If the firm bankrupts and disappears from the system leaving its site empty. The shares of the picked firm are equally distributed among all the other firms in the market in such a way that the normalization condition (1) holds. Compared to the original model we modified this step by including government intervention, modeled by the intervention parameter . In this Monte Carlo step, when a firm should bankrupt because , another random number is generated and compared with the parameter . If the firm is saved by the government and survives at this step despite the fact that . The algorithm goes straight to item 7. If the firm bankrupts anyway. Thus, the parameter describes the probability that the government will intervene and save the firm (with probability ) at risk from bankruptcy.
-
4.
If the firm survives and gets an opportunity to be active. It can move to one of the four randomly chosen neighboring sites. If the chosen site is unoccupied then it does not move. However, it interacts with the firm in that chosen site, in a way described in item 6 below.
-
5.
If there was an empty site and the firm moved there, the algorithm checks if it has any neighboring firms in the nearest and next-nearest lattice site of its new location. If there are no such firms, then the firm’s technology grows according to formula , where is a random number. This growth corresponds to the external technology diffusion since the company copies, although imperfectly, the technology of the world frontier. Of course, if the selected neighboring place was already occupied, the company remains in its site.
-
6.
There are two mechanisms of inner technology diffusion, merging and creating new firms – spin-offs. If the -th company found, after moving to a new lattice site, some randomly chosen neighboring firm , then with probability , the firm merges with the firm . The firm disappears from the system and the technology of the -th firm changes according to relation . The -th firm also acquires the shares of the merged firm, so . With probability , firms and create a spin-off. In this case, none of the firms disappear from the system. A position for the spin-off is chosen randomly out of the eight neighboring sites of the -th firm. The spin-off appears, only if the picked site is unoccupied. The spin-off’s technology level is and the shares are , where . Because the condition 1 has to be fulfilled, the shares of the company decrease by product and the company by . This step corresponds to the technology diffusion within the companies’ market.
-
7.
The algorithm returns to point 1. until all the firms have been chosen which ends this Monte Carlo step/site. Next, the algoritm goes to the subsequent Monte Carlo step/site.
In the case of a company’s bankruptcy, as described in item 3, the shares of the company are distributed equally between other firms in the system. We chose the same way of shares distribution as used in previous model [3]. This way of distribution allows for a straightforward comparison of our results with the corresponding in the previous work. It illustrates the role of the intervention parameter, which we introduce into the model. We also assume that after a company bankrupts, the other companies do not perform any additional actions. Their increase in shares is a result of the disappearance of one of the firms from the market and not a result of competing for the shares. Other ways of shares redistribution are also possible, for example, ones in which the freed shares are obtained by other companies proportionally to their present shares (preferential selection rule).
It is also worth realizing that random numbers and are parameterizing the random risk component of investing in innovation by a company.
Probability of a company’s survival is calculated according to the formula,
(8) |
where and .
Eq. (8) divides the technological development of a country (or companies’ market) into two phases. The first phase for and the second phase for . The first phase corresponds to the less technologically advanced countries (or companies’ markets). The second phase corresponds to countries (or companies’ markets) that are more developed and have a higher technology level. The parameter controls the market vulnerability to technological backwardness and thus susceptibility to bankruptcy. If this parameter has a smaller value, then this vulnerability is smaller and vice versa.
We chose, for example, the same parameters for our simulations as used in paper [3]. Those are: . The minimum number of companies necessary for the market survival (i.e., ensure the duration of the simulation) should be calibrated to empirical data. In principle, this choice is optional and the obvious condition must be met. When the number of firms in the system equals at time , then a randomly picked firm does not face the danger of bankruptcy. It means that items 2 – 3 of the algorithm are omitted and the firm goes directly from item 1 to 4.
In our program, the shares of every company are written in a double-precision floating-point format (double). However, it is not an exact representation. To ensure the normalization of market shares with satisfactory accuracy, we additionally introduce a dynamic correction of these shares in each Monte Carlo step per site. It ensures that the normalization condition is met with controlled accuracy (in our case, not exceeding 1%).
3 Results and discussion
3.1 Free companies’ market
Figure 1 shows the results for the case of no government intervention () that is, for the free companies market. Three basic quantities are measured at the beginning of every Monte Carlo step per site : (i) the current number of firms in the system , (ii) the weighted average technology of existing firms , and (iii) the average to frontier technology ratio . The results shown in Fig. 1 are the reference situation for other cases where interventionism is present (i.e., for ).

In this model, the evolution of the companies’ market goes through three stages [3]. For the case of free companies’ market, the firms with the lowest technology level are eliminated in about 50 time steps (the first stage), and the average technology increases as a result. In the second stage, which lasts for about another 150 steps, the technological advancement of the market comes mostly from internal technology diffusion, namely from spin-offs and merges. In the last (third) stage (that lasts until the end of the simulation), the technology grows exponentially, benefiting from external diffusion – getting the technology from the world frontier. Apparently, in the third plot of Figure 1, value is decaying slowly to a stable level after reaching its maximum around MCS/site t = 220. The relative average reaches a plateau when the number of firms reaches its plateau. Both plateaus are determined by parameter , which we set, for example, equal to 10. In this third stage, when the number of remaining firms is already small, item 5 of the algorithm is the primary source of technology growth. Therefore, as decays, so does the , since the pool of firms that can copy the leader shrinks. Indeed, all of those stages are well seen in Fig. 1.
In Secs. 3.2 – 3.5 we investigate four significant cases of interventionism. The egalitarian in which all the companies have access to the government’s aid, and three other cases in which only the companies with certain technology level can receive support. In the egalitarian case, any company at risk of failure can be chosen to receive another chance thanks to the government intervention and possibly be saved as described in point 3 of the algorithm. In the other three non-egalitarian cases, the government chooses to support only companies with low, medium, or high technology levels. A given company is qualified for one of these three cases when its technology is below one standard deviation from the mean technology in the system, in between or above one , respectively. We define as:
(9) |
Several values of for all of the cases were examined. However, only results for a few characteristic values are selected in this work to portray changes in the dynamics as increases within the wide range .
3.2 Egalitarian intervention
Figure 2 presents some of the results for the egalitarian intervention case.

First of all, as the probability of government intervention grows, the first stage lasts longer. In the egalitarian case, any company can be a beneficiary; in particular, a company with a low technology level. Therefore it takes more time for those companies to disappear from the system. This makes the initial growth of the average technology level slower. This can be seen in Fig. 2 when comparing the shape of in the first 100 steps for different values of . For sufficiently high , the average to frontier technology ratio is dipping instead of growing since the frontier technology grows much faster (exponentially) than .
The most surprising results are for the very high intervention probability . From Fig. 2 we see that when the system enters the regime with as in formula 8, the technology growth becomes very unstable as indicated by the high standard deviation. At the time , with higher , the market has, paradoxically, a lower average technology compared to the situations with lower intervention probabilities .
3.3 High technology intervention
For the case in which the government supports only the firms with technology over one standard deviation () above the average, there are no visible differences from the case shown in Fig. 1. This type of intervention does not influence the market significantly because the firms with high technology are already not likely to go bankrupt as follows from Eq. (8). Hence, there is a negligible number of government interventions involved in this case. For this reason, we have not visualized the results in the form of plots.
3.4 Low technology intervention

When the government supports only the firms with low technology level, then the first stage, when typically low technology firms are usually eliminated, is prolonged. It is similar to the egalitarian intervention case. However, in contrast to the egalitarian intervention case, once those protected firms are eliminated, the growth continues undisturbed. That is, the ratio is almost unaffected for the third stage.
3.5 Medium technology intervention

The government’s aid towards the firms with the medium technology level, namely between , can have a visible impact on the growth dynamics of the market. Figure 4 shows that high intervention probability, in this case, destabilizes the market growth in the later stage. This is due to huge fluctuations expressed by the very high value. The first stage lasting about 50 steps is undisturbed and is the same as the no intervention case in Figure 1. In this stage, mostly the weaker firms are going bankrupt as the government rarely intervenes. In the second and third phases, the dynamic is similar to the one with random intervention shown in Figure 2. This should be expected since the low technology firms have already disappeared, and the intervention in the high segment does not influence the dynamic. Therefore, it is the intervention in the medium segment that can potentially have the most significant impact on the growth dynamic in the long term.
3.6 The unstable growth for the strong intervention case
Presumably, one of the most interesting results is a rapid increase of the quantity vs. time (in MCS/site) for , as shown in Figs. 2 and 4. After the system reaches the range , the formula for the survival probability changes according to Eq. (8) and the system enters a new (last) stage. That is, the survival probability goes from the definition given by the first and third lines in Eq. (8) to the second and fourth lines. Hence, the average technology grows rapidly in an unstable manner in the case, as its large fluctuations are observed herein (i.e., the large standard deviation ). This sudden change to a highly fluctuating dynamic of requires an explanation, which we provide below. However, the question why the dynamic switches to a rapid growth only after the technology is still a challenge.
The origin of the behavior mentioned above lies in the way the intervention was implemented in the algorithm (see Sec. 2.2 for details) imitating a real interaction. This results in two effects that we list below.
-
(i)
After the intervention saves a firm (see item 3 for details), the algorithm goes straight to item 7. It means that the firm behaves passively. The saved company can not do anything else at this Monte Carlo step. This passive behavior happens very often for high , since the intervention is very likely at any time. If the concentration of companies is greater than the minimum concentration (equals , then instead of item 5 of the algorithm, the less effective item 6 of the algorithm works. It results in companies’ technology growing significantly slower than or almost in technological stagnation. As a result the quantity decreases, since grows (exponentially) according to Eq. (3).
-
(ii)
Near the threshold (when for the first time), the situation already changes because the concentration of companies is close to minimal (cf. Figs. 2 – 4, especially for plots with ). At this point, we are in the higher technology phase (i.e., ). Hence, the probability of company survival is given, in general, by the third and fourth lines in Eq. (8). In principle, the inequality never fulfills, so only the third line works effectively. Since the concentration of companies is low, the external technology diffusion (defined in item 5 of the algorithm) becomes a possibility for the firms to increase their technology level. The meeting of two companies (located in neighboring lattice sites) is improbable, causing de facto disabling of item 6. The relative mean value achieves the plateau. It happens when the increase of mean value is (to a good approximation) in a hundred percent caused by a global (external) frontier.
We can conclude that the dominant process for the case is described in item 5 of the algorithm (see Sec. 2.2 for details). It leads to a rapid increase in mean technology and next to the plateau of its relative value.
Moreover, we investigated the specific time for the unmodified algorithm at which the transition () occurred and depicted it in Fig. 5. The result obtained is very characteristic because it shows that the level of market technology will never exceed the particular threshold as the level of intervention tends to 100%.

Figure 5 shows that as grows, it takes the market more time to reach the high technology phase in which . When approaches 1, goes to infinity, i.e., the market will never reach the high technology phase.
When , the firms never bankrupt (cf. item 3). They can only disappear via merging with neighboring firms. Besides, new firms are created in the form of spin-offs (cf. item 6).
3.6.1 Remarks on the modified version of the algorithm
To further investigate the source of the unstable growth of the value, we modified the item 3 of the algorithm. The modification is as follows: after the intervention, the firm can still act, which means the algorithm goes to item 5 instead of 7. Hence, the phase with unstable technology growth disappears111More precisely, is much larger (longer than 2000 MCS/site) in this case., which we show in Fig. 7 by the dashed curve. We emphasize that both algorithms can describe the real situation. It is because there may be companies that, after the intervention, ”rest on their laurels” (unmodified algorithm) as well as others that invest in new technologies (the modified version of the algorithm).
The result obtained by the modified algorithm we present in Fig. 7. We show that the number of firms in the system is on a very high, stable level throughout the entire simulation. It is because new spin-offs are created more often than companies disappearing through merging or bankruptcy. Therefore, the firms in the market can rarely ever subject an external technology diffusion, which happens if they have no neighbors. The external diffusion is the way that allows for the fastest increase in technology in the long times. However, with large firm concentration, it is improbable. In the modified case, we observe that the system never enters a stage of fast growth, which is shown by the dashed curve in Fig. 7.


4 Conclusions
In our work, we considered two characteristic variants of the model of government interventionism in the companies’ market. We describe interventionism by one parameter only. It determines the level of interventionism. That is, the level of interventionism we define by the probability of government intervention . The value of indicates the absence of such interventionism, and the value of indicates the certainty of interventionism. Notably, the government intervenes with probability if the company is threatened with bankruptcy, i.e., when the probability of bankruptcy is greater than zero.
Both model variants differ significantly in the behavior of companies following government intervention, although algorithms differ a little. In the first variant, after the intervention, the company is passive. In a given Monte Carlo step, its technological level remains unchanged. However, in the second (modified) variant, the firm is active, i.e., it can increase its technology level in the current Monte Carlo step.
In both model variants, only three different growth channels of the mean technology level of the companies’ market exist. They are determined by items 5 and 6 of the algorithm (see Sec. 2.2 for details). These channels have a well-defined probability of appearing.
We show that government intervention leaves its mark on the growth dynamics of the company market. We found that for most of the values of , government intervention does not influence the market significantly. A significant impact of government interventionism takes place when is close to at least 0.9.
When the aid is given randomly, and the government does not distinguish firms based on their technology, it can have a disruptive effect on market growth. High intervention probability means the companies do not have to compete anymore because the government will almost always save companies from going bankrupt. The most drastic effects of the strong intervention are visible when one compares the value of the average to the frontier technology ratio at for different . With high , is volatile, and with asymptotic times its value is around 0.5, compared to the case with when it is close to 1. It means that the country with strong government intervention might never catch up with countries with lower intervention probability.
We also found that the volatile growth at long times disappears when the firms are allowed to act right after being saved by the government.
We are aware that our model should also include the possibility of raising the technological level of companies through government interventionism. The positive effect of interventionism on technological expansion was observed in a study comparing Hong Kong and Singapore [8]. However, at the moment, none of the studied variants of the model supply such a possibility. We plan to investigate this potentially beneficial effect soon, as well as further extensions of the model. For example, we could add a budget variable to describe the firms more realistically and allow them to purchase assets from other companies to improve their technology and increase their market shares gradually.
5 Acknowledgments
We thank Professor Marcel Ausloos for an interesting discussion during the 10th Symposium FENS 2019 in NCBJ Otwock – Swierk, Poland.
References
- [1] Stephen K Aikins. Political economy of government intervention in the free market system. Administrative Theory & Praxis, 31(3):403–408, 2009. https://doi.org/10.2753/ATP1084-1806310309.
- [2] Marcel Ausloos, Paulette Clippe, and Andrzej Pekalski. Model of macroeconomic evolution in stable regionally dependent economic fields. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 337(1-2):269–287, 2004. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2004.01.029.
- [3] K Cichy. Microeconomic evolution model with technology diffusion. Acta Physica Polonica A, 121(2B), 2012. doi: 10.12693/APhysPolA.121.B-16.
- [4] Krzysztof Cichy. Human capital and technological progress as the determinants of economic growth. National Bank of Poland Working Paper, (60), 2009. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1752094 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1752094.
- [5] Mrinal Datta-Chaudhuri. Market failure and government failure. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(3):25–39, 1990. DOI: 10.1257/jep.4.3.25.
- [6] Pablo Ruiz Nápoles et al. Macro policies for climate change: Free market or state intervention? World Social and Economic Review, 2014(3, 2014):90, 2014.
- [7] Robert R Schaller. Moore’s law: past, present and future. IEEE spectrum, 34(6):52–59, 1997. doi: 10.1109/6.591665.
- [8] Jue Wang. Innovation and government intervention: A comparison of singapore and hong kong. Research Policy, 47(2):399–412, 2018. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2017.12.008.