Bounds on Choquet Risk Measures in Finite
Product Spaces with Ambiguous Marginals
Abstract.
We investigate the problem of finding upper and lower bounds for a Choquet risk measure of a nonlinear function of two risk factors, when the marginal distributions of the risk factors are ambiguous and represented by nonadditive measures on the marginal spaces and the joint nonadditive distribution on the product space is unknown. We treat this problem as a generalization of the optimal transport problem to the setting of nonadditive measures. We provide explicit characterizations of the optimal solutions for finite marginal spaces, and we investigate some of their properties. We further discuss the connections with linear programming, showing that the optimal transport problems for capacities are linear programs, and we also characterize their duals explicitly. Finally, we investigate a series of numerical examples, including a comparison with the classical optimal transport problem, and applications to counterparty credit risk.
Key Words and Phrases: Risk management, Optimal Transport, Non-Additive Measures, Risk Measures, Cooperative Games.
1. Introduction
An important problem in the literature on credit risk management is that of determining bounds on the Credit Valuation Adjustment (CVA), that is, the price adjustment on a given derivatives portfolio to account for potential counterparty credit risk losses (e.g., Garcia-Cespedes \BOthers. (\APACyear2010); Glasserman \BBA Yang (\APACyear2018); Rosen \BBA Saunders (\APACyear2010, \APACyear2012)). A portfolio’s counterparty credit risk exposure depends on market risk factors, and the likelihood of a counterparty default depends on credit risk factors. Consequently, the computation of CVA requires the modelling of potential portfolio losses as functions of these two sets of dependent risk factors. There is a large literature on the required credit risk models (e.g., McNeil \BOthers. (\APACyear2015) and the references therein). In practice, counterparty exposures often depend on a large number of risk factors (equity prices, interest rates, exchange rates, etc.), leading to several challenges with their measurement and management (e.g., Brigo \BOthers. (\APACyear2013); Gregory (\APACyear2020)).
Joint models of market and credit risk are, in general, very difficult to develop and estimate in practice. Hence, even when the marginal distributions of the market and credit risk factors are known, there is still uncertainty about their joint distribution and about the ensuing CVA computation. Glasserman \BBA Yang (\APACyear2018) examine bounds on CVA arising from the uncertainty about the dependence structure. They formulated the problem of finding the worst-case CVA with respect to the dependence structure between the risk factors as an Optimal Transport (OT) problem. In related work, Memartoluie \BOthers. (\APACyear2017) considered in a formal way the problem of finding the worst-case Expected Shortfall (ES) of a nonlinear function of market risk and credit risk, given the marginal distributions of the factors, and they showed that in the case of finite sample spaces, the problem is equivalent to a linear program. Recently, Ghossoub \BOthers. (\APACyear2023) extended the problem to general spaces and to spectral risk measures. They examined the problem of finding a worst-case spectral risk measure of a nonlinear function of two risk factors with known marginals, with respect to their dependence structure. They formulated the problem as a generalized OT problem and provided a strong duality theory similar to the Kantorovich duality in classical OT theory.
OT is the subject of a large literature, dating back to the seminal work of Monge (\APACyear1781) and Kantorovich (\APACyear1942). Monge (\APACyear1781) considered the problem of minimizing the total cost (measured using the Euclidean distance between the source and the target) of moving one mass distribution to another among all volume-preserving maps. Kantorovich (\APACyear1942, \APACyear1948) later relaxed this problem by expanding the feasible set to all measure couplings with given marginal distributions and developed a duality theory for the relaxed problem. Modern OT is a large and rapidly developing field (e.g., Santambrogio (\APACyear2015); Villani (\APACyear2008)) with applications to several areas within mathematics (e.g., Rachev \BBA Rüschendorf (\APACyear1998); Villani (\APACyear2003)), and applied fields such as physics (e.g., Guillen \BBA Kitagawa (\APACyear2017); R. McCann (\APACyear2020)), statistics (e.g., Panaretos \BBA Zemel (\APACyear2022); Zhang \BOthers. (\APACyear2020)), economics (e.g., Carlier \BBA Zhang (\APACyear2020); Galichon (\APACyear2016); R\BPBIJ. McCann \BBA Zhang (\APACyear2019)), finance (e.g., Henry-Labordère (\APACyear2017); Eckstein \BOthers. (\APACyear2021)), and machine learning (e.g., Peyré \BBA Cuturi (\APACyear2019); Torres \BOthers. (\APACyear2021)), for instance.
In the aforementioned literature, the marginal distributions of risk factors are assumed to be given and known, but their dependence structure is unknown. In particular, the marginals are (additive) probability measures. As a result, problems of bounding risk measures of loss functions can be formulated as (generalized) OT problems, with various cost functions, depending on the particular application. In many such applications, particularly related to the modelling of decision-making under ambiguity or vagueness in beliefs, a decision-maker’s attitude toward, and sensitivity to ambiguity in beliefs is represented by monotone set functions that lack additivity. Such objects are called capacities or nonadditive measures. See, for example, the work of Quiggin (\APACyear1982, \APACyear1993); Schmeidler (\APACyear1986, \APACyear1989); Yaari (\APACyear1987) for theoretical foundations. In particular, the seminal contribution of Schmeidler (\APACyear1986, \APACyear1989) axiomatized models of decision-making under ambiguity in which the decision-maker’s preferences admit a representation in terms of an expected utility with respect to a nonadditive measure. Such expectations are defined through the notion of a Choquet integral with respect to a capacity.111Note that our use of the word capacity here is distinct from the usage in the literature on optimal transport with capacity constraints (e.g., Korman \BBA McCann (\APACyear2015); Korman \BOthers. (\APACyear2015); Pennanen \BBA Perkkiö (\APACyear2019)), where the “capacity constraint” imposes an upper bound on the density of the coupling. We refer to Denneberg (\APACyear1994) or Marinacci \BBA Montrucchio (\APACyear2004) for more about capacities and Choquet integration.
In this paper, we are interested in the problem of bounding a risk measure of a nonlinear function of two risk factors, but where (i) the marginal distributions of the risk factors are ambiguous, and represented by nonadditive measures on the marginal spaces; and, (ii) the objective function is a Choquet integral. As in Glasserman \BBA Yang (\APACyear2018), we consider the case of two risk factors defined on finite spaces. We assume given (marginal) capacities on these spaces, representing the ambiguous distributions of the risk factors, and consider the problem of finding the joint capacity on the product space with these given marginals, which maximizes or minimizes the Choquet integral of a given portfolio loss function. We treat this problem as a generalization of the OT problem to the setting of nonadditive measures. We provide explicit characterizations of the optimal solutions for finite marginal spaces, and we investigate some of their properties. Additionally, we explore connections to linear programming and present a version of the Kantorovich duality.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents definitions and background material needed for the rest of the paper. Section 3 formulates the problem of bounding Choquet risk measures as an OT problem with nonadditive marginals. Section 4 presents a mathematical formulation of the OT problem for capacities, investigates properties of its feasible set, and gives characterizations and explicit formulas for its solution. In addition, we further study properties of the optimal capacities (in particular, non-emptiness of the core) in terms of the corresponding properties of the marginal capacities. The explicit formula for the core of the minimizer can be found in that section. Moreover, as in the case of measures, the OT problem for capacities can be formulated as a linear program (see Torra (\APACyear2023) for a related result), and we characterize its dual in Section 5. Section 6 presents numerical examples comparing our problem to the classical OT problem and illustrating its use in a counterparty credit risk application. Finally, Section 7 concludes.
2. Preliminaries
2.1. Capacities and Choquet Integration
Denote by the vector space of all bounded and -measurable real-valued functions on a given measurable space . Then is a Banach space (Dunford \BBA Schwartz, \APACyear1958, IV.5.1), where denotes the supnorm.
Let denote the linear space of all bounded finitely additive set functions on . When equipped with the variation norm , is a Banach space, and is isometrically isomorphic to the norm-dual of the Banach space (e.g., (Dunford \BBA Schwartz, \APACyear1958, IV.5.1)) via the duality . Denote by the collection of all countably additive elements of . Then is a -closed (and hence complete) linear subspace of . Henceforth, a collection of probability measures will be called weak∗-compact if it is compact in the weak∗ topology .
Definition 2.1.
A capacity (nonadditive measure) on a measurable space is a finite set function such that and is monotone; that is, for any , whenever . When , the capacity is said to be normalized.
The conjugate of a capacity on is the finite set function defined by , for all . Then is also a capacity, and if is normalized then so is .
A capacity is called supermodular (resp. submodular) if
The core of a capacity on , denoted by , is the collection of all bounded finitely additive measures on such that , for all . When nonempty, is weak∗-compact and convex.
Definition 2.2.
Let be a capacity on . The Choquet integral of with respect to is defined by
where the integrals are taken in the sense of Riemann.
Definition 2.3.
Two functions are said to be comonotonic if
If , then the Choquet integral with respect to is the usual Lebesgue integral with respect to (e.g., (Marinacci \BBA Montrucchio, \APACyear2004, p. 59)). Unlike the Lebesgue integral, the Choquet integral is not an additive operator on . However, the Choquet integral is additive over comonotonic functions.
Proposition 2.4.
Let be a capacity on .
-
(1)
If are comonotonic, then .
-
(2)
If are such that , then .
-
(3)
For all and all , then .
-
(4)
If is submodular, then for any , .
-
(5)
If is supermodular, then for any , .
2.2. Risk Measures
Risk measures are real-valued functionals defined on some collection of random variables on a given probability space. They are often used either as a quantification of riskiness of a given financial position, or as a way to determine adequate capital requirements (e.g., Föllmer \BBA Schied (\APACyear2016), McNeil \BOthers. (\APACyear2015), or Rüschendorf (\APACyear2013)). Formally, a risk measure is a mapping , where is a prespecified collection of random variables on a given probablity space . Common properties of risk measures include:
-
R.1
(Monotonicity) , for all such that , -a.s.
-
R.2
(Positive Homogeneity) , for all and all .
-
R.3
(Cash Invariance) , for all and .
-
R.4
(Subadditivity) for all .
-
R.5
(Comonotonic Additivity) for all that are comonotonic.
-
R.6
(Law Invariance) when and have the same distribution under .
A coherent risk measure Artzner \BOthers. (\APACyear1999); Delbaen (\APACyear2002) is a risk measure that satisfies Axioms R.1-R.4, which are considered desirable for effective risk management. A practically relevant example of a coherent risk measure, frequently used in the banking and insurance industries, is the Expected Shortfall (ES), also known as the Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR). If is the left-continuous quantile of , and , then the expected shortfall of at the confidence level is:
If the space is nonatomic, then a coherent, comonotonic additive, and law-invariant risk measure admits a representation as a spectral risk measure (e.g., (Föllmer \BBA Schied, \APACyear2016, Theorem 4.93), Kusuoka (\APACyear2001), (McNeil \BOthers., \APACyear2015, Proposition 8.18), Shapiro (\APACyear2013)), that is, as a risk measure of the form
for some probability measure on . Moreover, by a classical result on Choquet integration (e.g., Schmeidler (\APACyear1986)), monotone and comonotonic additive risk measures admit a representation in terms of a Choquet integral of the form
for some capacity on .
The class of spectral risk measures is flexible and rich enough to encompass several of the most popular and practically relevant risk measures. Additionally, there is a tight relationship between spectral risk measures and the subclass of Choquet risk measures called Distortion Risk Measures (DRM). These are Choquet risk measures for which the capacity is of the form , for some increasing function such that . The function is called a distortion function, or a probability weighting function. Indeed, it can be shown (e.g., Acerbi (\APACyear2002); Föllmer \BBA Schied (\APACyear2016); Kusuoka (\APACyear2001); McNeil \BOthers. (\APACyear2015); Shapiro (\APACyear2013)) that a spectral risk measure also admits the representation
where is a nonnegative and increasing function that satisfies . This function is called the spectral function. For instance, for the Expected Shortfall (ES) at level , the spectral function is given by , that is, . Moreover, letting
it follows that is a distortion function, and it can be shown that is DRM with respect to , that is,
2.3. Finite State Spaces
Suppose that is a nonempty finite set, and let be the collection of all of its subsets. Throughout, we identify measures on any nonempty finite set with vectors through . Let be a capacity on .
Definition 2.5.
The Möbius transform of a capacity is defined as
The Choquet integral of a function with respect to the capacity can be represented in terms of the Möbius transform as follows:
(2.1) |
with
(2.2) |
where , and represents the minimum of on (e.g., (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Theorem 4.95)). See Grabisch (\APACyear2016) and Marinacci \BBA Montrucchio (\APACyear2004) for more information about the Möbius transform.
Definition 2.6.
Let be a nonempty finite set, and let be a collection of subsets containing and the empty set. Suppose that a function satisfies , and whenever , . The capacity on defined by
is called the outer envelope of . The capacity defined by
is called the inner envelope of .
When it is necessary to make explicit in the notation, we will write for the outer envelope, and for the inner envelope. It is easy to see that .222Fix , and with . Then . Minimizing over containing yields , and then maximizing over contained in gives that .
Definition 2.7.
Given nonempty finite sets , we define to be the collection of all subsets of of the form with and . We define to be the collection of all subsets of of the form with and , and either or (or both). That is is the collection of all sets either of the form with or with .
Sets in product spaces and their projections will feature prominently in the optimal solutions of our optimization problems. The notation in the next definition will be convenient.
Definition 2.8.
For a set , define:
It is easy to see that , and .
Definition 2.9.
Let be an integer. A capacity on is called -monotone if for any sets ,
The capacity is called -alternating if the above inequality is reversed. A 2-monotone capacity is supermodular, while a 2-alternating capacity is submodular. If is -monotone for all , it is called totally monotone, and if it is -alternating for all , it is called totally alternating.
3. Bounds on Choquet Risk Measures
3.1. Problem Formulation
We consider the case of a portfolio whose loss depends on two risk factors defined on two finite spaces. We assume given (marginal) capacities on these spaces, representing the ambiguous distributions of the risk factors, and we consider the problem of finding the joint capacity on the product space with these given marginals that maximizes or minimizes the Choquet integral of a given portfolio loss function.
Specifically, let and be non-empty finite sets, and let and be random variables on and , respectively. We are given a function representing the loss on a portfolio consisting of the risk factors and . The distributional uncertainty, or ambiguity, about the risk factors is represented by capacities on and on , to be interpreted as ambiguous beliefs about the distributions of and , respectively.
A joint distribution for and is represented by a capacity on the product space , such that the projections onto and are and , respectively.
Definition 3.1.
Let and be nonempty finite sets, a capacity on , a capacity on , and a capacity on .
-
(1)
The marginal capacities of on and , respectively, are defined by
-
(2)
The set of all capacities on such that and is denoted by .
We are interested in evaluating a risk measure of the portfolio loss function in the case where is a Choquet integral of with respect to a capacity on :
In our framework, while the capacities and are given, no information about the dependence structure (and hence the joint distribution) of the two risk factors is available. Therefore, computing a Choquet risk measure of the portfolio loss function is not possible without further information. A natural question that arises is whether we are able to establish upper and lower bounds on the value of such a risk measures with respect to the uncertrainty about the joint capacity . Specifically, our problem is that of finding capacities that maximize or minimize the Choquet integral of among all capacities in :
(3.1) |
Problem (3.1) can be seen as a generalization of the optimal transport problem to the setting of nonadditive measures.
4. The Optimal Transport Problem for Capacities
In this section, we formulate the optimal transport problem for capacities. Once the problem is formulated, we investigate properties of the feasible set. Understanding the lattice structure of the feasible set leads immediately to explicit formulas for the optimizers.
Definition 4.1.
Let and be non-empty finite sets, and let and be probability measures on and , respectively. Denote by the set of measures on that have the marginals on and on . That is,
Given a function , the optimal transport minimization problem is:
(4.1) |
Similarly, given a function , the optimal transport maximization problem is:
(4.2) |
Both the maximization and minimization problems are linear in . Because is convex and compact, optimal solutions exist, and the set of optimal solutions contains at least one extreme point of the feasible set. For instance, when and both and are uniform measures, by Birkhoff’s Theorem there exists an optimal solution supported on , for some permutation .
Definition 4.2.
Let and be nonempty finite sets and be a capacity on . The marginal capacities of on and , respectively, are defined by
for all , .
In particular, for two probability measures and , , where the latter is defined in Definition 3.1. The proof of the following result is straightforward.
Lemma 4.3.
Let and be normalized capacities on and , respectively. Then if and only if .
Given a function , consider the analogue of the optimal transport problem on capacity couplings, i.e. finding capacities to maximize or minimize the Choquet integral of among all capacities in :
We note that, since in general, it is worthwhile to develop the theories for the minimum and maximum problems in parallel.
4.1. The Feasible Set and Its Properties
The first thing to observe about the feasible set is that it is nonempty.
Proposition 4.4.
Let and be normalized capacities on and respectively. Then .
Proof.
Define the function by for with and . It is easy to verify that both and are in .
We note that we could have used in place of in the above argument, and reached the same conclusion. Since is defined by a finite system of linear equalities and inequalities, and for any set , we in fact have the following result.
Proposition 4.5.
Let and be normalized capacities on and . Then is a compact, convex polyhedron in .
Remark 4.6.
-
•
A capacity is called the unanimity game associated with the set if if , and otherwise. If is the unanimity game associated with , and is the unanimity game associated with , then the unanimity game associated with is in .
-
•
Suppose that is a totally monotone capacity on with Möbius transform , and is a totally monotone capacity on with Möbius transform , then defined to be the capacity on with Möbius transform given by
is a totally monotone capacity in .333It should be noted that if and are capacities, this construction does not in general result in a capacity. A counterexample is given by , , with (see Dyckerhoff (\APACyear2022)). For further information on this construction, see Bauer (\APACyear2012); Destercke (\APACyear2013); Ghirardato (\APACyear1997); Hendon \BOthers. (\APACyear1991); Koshevoy (\APACyear1998); Walley \BBA Fine (\APACyear1982). Combining the above argument with Lemma 4.3, it is easy to see that if and are totally alternating, then there exists a totally alternating capacity .
-
•
A possibility measure is defined as a normalized capacity such that , for any sets and . From this definition, it is easy to see that (and by normalization, there must exist such that ). If and are possibility measures, then defines a possibility measure in . The conjugate of a possibility measure is called a necessity measure (which satisfies ). Again, using Lemma 4.3 one can show that if and are necessity measures, then there exists a necessity measure .
A capacity is said to be balanced if its core is nonempty. The next result demonstrates that there exists a balanced if and only if both and are balanced.
Proposition 4.7.
Let and be normalized capacities on nonempty finite sets and , respectively. Then the following are equivalent:
-
(1)
Both and have nonempty cores (i.e., and ).
-
(2)
There exists with a nonempty core.
Proof.
Suppose that and . Define a measure on by and additivity. Further, define by for and , and take . It is easy to see that . Let , and consider , . Then:
This implies that , for all . Therefore, .
Conversely, let and , and define for , . With , we have
with equality when , and therefore . The same argument yields .
Remark 4.8.
It should be noted that there can exist capacities on and on with nonempty cores and an element with an empty core. Consider , , and take and to be probability measures on and respectively, giving equal weight to each point. Define to give value zero to the empty set, 1 to , to any subset consisting of a single point, to any subset consisting of two points, and to any subset consisting of three points. Any element would have to satisfy , and , and thus , contradicting .
4.2. Lattice Structure of the Feasible Set and Characterization of the Optimal Solutions
If we think of normalized capacities on as functions on the collection of subsets , then given two capacities and , we can define, for :
With these definitions, and are both capacities, and the collection of all normalized capacities is a bounded distributive lattice, with largest element giving value 1 to all nonempty sets, and smallest element giving value 0 to all sets except , which has value 1.444We note that there is another way of defining lattice operations on capacities, involving setwise maxima and minima of their Möbius transforms. See Grabisch (\APACyear2016); Marinacci \BBA Montrucchio (\APACyear2004) for details.
Since all capacities in have the same values for sets of the form , for , and , for , we have that is a distributive sublattice. Furthermore, is bounded (as a lattice) with maximum and minimum elements given by taking setwise maxima and minima:
The next result follows from the definition of the Choquet integral.
Theorem 4.9.
For , and and described above, we have
Proof.
We first verify that both and are indeed feasible. Note that if for , then for all , and therefore . Similarly, if with , then . Furthermore, by their definitions, both and are non-negative non-decreasing set functions, i.e. capacities. In other words, we have that .
Now, by the definition in (4.2), and achieve the set-wise infimum and supremum among , respectively. Let . Then:
The proof for is similar.
It is possible to find explicit expressions for and .
Theorem 4.10.
For any ,
Proof.
Define by
Let and be the outer and inner envelope of as defined in Definition 2.6 with . From the monotonicity of on (with the inclusion order), it is not hard to see that, for any with , one has . Similarly, for any with , we have . By definition, and are clearly non-negative and non-decreasing, so .
For any , and . Therefore, and . If , then , and if , then . The monotonicity of and then imply that
To complete the proof, we will show that and . For any and , the relation implies that
and implies that
Therefore,
This implies, and . The equalities hold because .
Remark 4.11.
If we explicitly include the dependence of the optimizers on the marginal capacities, i.e. when given write and for the smallest and largest elements of , then it is easy to show that and .
Remark 4.12.
-
•
Suppose that is the unanimity game associated with and is the unanimity game associated with , and . Then if either or , and zero otherwise. On the other hand, if for all there exists such that and for all there exists such that , and otherwise.
-
•
Suppose that and are possibility measures, and define by . Then given ,
Define by , then
When and are necessity measures, then and can be calculated using the previous remark.
Consider . For a fixed , define
with defined similarly. Then
Similarly , and therefore
and
using the fact that we have assumed and to be normalized.
Using a similar argument,
and . Thus,
and
To conclude, we have
4.3. Balancedness and Cores of the Optimal Solutions
Since , for all and , we immediately obtain the following result.
Proposition 4.13.
Let and be normalized capacities on and , respectively. The following statements regarding the cores hold.
-
(1)
If , then for all .
-
(2)
If , then for all .
-
(3)
In particular, iff and .
Proof.
Suppose , then for any fixed and any , one has , with both equalities hold at . Therefore, . Using the same argument, one can show (2). Proposition 4.7 together with (2) implies (3).
However, is typically empty, as per the following result.
Proposition 4.14.
Suppose that and are normalized capacities on and , respectively, and , . Then .
Proof.
Let and be partitions of and respectively, and define:
Then , , so that for the disjoint sets and , .
We can in fact explicitly identify in terms of and .
Proposition 4.15.
Let and be normalized capacities on and , respectively. Then
Proof.
Let , and for each fixed , define , and . Clearly . Furthermore, for , we have
since . Thus, , and similarly .
Conversely, suppose that with and . Clearly, . Let , and note that and . Then
That is, .
Remark 4.16.
By (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Corollary 2.23 (ii)), is supermodular if and only if for every and , , where , and is defined similarly. It is well-known that if is supermodular, then (e.g., (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Theorem 3.15)).
Let , and , and let be the additive (and therefore supermodular) capacity with , and , with defined on in the same way. Define:
and . Note that , , so . Also, , , so . Furthermore, , , , and , so , and . Thus, we conclude that while has a nonempty core, it is not supermodular.
Definition 4.17.
A capacity on is said to be exact if for every , there exists a core element such that .
We have seen that is typically empty, so that will not be exact. In the case when and are exact, we may ask whether is exact. That is, we define the capacity by:
and we ask whether .
Remark 4.18.
In general as defined above need not be either submodular or supermodular. To see this, consider the case for some , with and being uniform probability measures, and let be the conjugate of .555We prefer to avoid the cumbersome notation . Then
By Birkhoff’s Theorem, the optimum (and similarly ) is achieved by measures that put mass on points for some permutation . Consider , and . Then it is easy to see that , while . Thus , and , so is not supermodular (and therefore is not submodular, see (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Theorem 2.20)). On the other hand, consider , and . Then , and . We therefore have that , and (e.g., (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Theorem 2.16)). Thus is not supermodular (and is not submodular).
Remark 4.19.
Let , and , and take and to be two probability measures on that are not equal. Then , and , so that . Notice that any element of is also in . is compact, and for any fixed , is a continuous function on and therefore its minimum is attained. Consider the set and . We have that , and therefore . Suppose that was exact. Then there is a such that . But then is concentrated on the diagonal , contradicting the fact that . This implies that is not exact.
5. Linear Programming and the Kantorovich Duality for Capacities
In this section, we formulate the optimal transport problem for capacities as a linear program, and we present its dual. Recall that the Choquet integral of with respect to a capacity on can be written as
where
While this expression is not linear in , it is linear in , and since the constraints defining are all linear (see Proposition 4.5), the problem of minimizing over all becomes a linear program:
(5.1) | |||
(5.2) |
(e.g., (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, pp. 81-82)). Recall that a subset of is in if for some or for some .
The dual of the above linear program is given by
(5.3) |
(5.4) |
Let be an optimal solution to (5.3 - 5.4). Then complementary slackness implies that, for any ,
(5.5) |
Remark 5.1.
Remark 5.2.
The dual of the minimization Optimal Transport problem is equivalent to the problem
(5.9) |
(5.10) |
To see this, we will show, by the following change of variables666This corresponds to the situation derived from a set function , where , and , the co-Möbius transform, with similar conventions for , see (Grabisch, \APACyear2016, Table A.2, p. 440).
that the objectives are equal and that the constraints can be derived from each other.
First, the objective function becomes
To see that the constraints are equivalent, notice that the above transformation can be inverted as
Furthermore, for any , recall
Using the same inversion formula, we obtain
For any non-empty set , sum all constraints with a right-hand side involving with . The right-hand side term of (5.4) becomes
The sum of terms on the left-hand side of (5.4) will yield a sum involving , which is
and a sum involving , which is
By summing the above terms, we obtain
(5.11) |
The last equality comes from the observation that there exists an one-to-one mapping between and by the map , and thus the first and third terms in the second line of (5.11) cancel out. Therefore, one can derive the equations in (5.10) from those in (5.4). Similarly, one can also prove the opposite direction by using the above change of variables. ∎
Remark 5.3.
By a similar argument, the dual of the maximization Optimal Transport problem is equivalent to
(5.12) |
(5.13) |
6. Numerical Examples
6.1. A Comparison with the Optimal Transport Problem for Additive Measures
In this section, we compare the optimal transport problem for capacities with the classical optimal transport problem (for measures) via numerical simulations. Assume that and are two finite subsets of with and , and and are probability measures on and , respectively. Given the quadratic function on , the classical optimal transport problem is to find
while the optimal transport minimization problem for capacities seeks
where represents the Choquet integral of with respect to . The latter problem will have a lower minimum since its feasible set is larger.
We use the Python package AMPL to solve the linear program for the classical optimal transport minimization. However, the linear program for the optimal transport for capacities is quite large when both sets have cardinality greater than 5. For example, when , the number of variables in the linear program is , and the number of constraints is . These numbers will become astronomical if and exceed 20. For the case when and , the number of variables for the linear program is larger than , and the number of constraints is larger than ; while the number of variables for the classical optimal transport problem is and the number of constraints is only . Therefore, in this case, solving the classical optimal transport problem using linear programming methods is still fast, but the linear program for capacities cannot be solved using numerical methods. However, using the explicit solution provided in Theorem 4.10, the minimum can be computed in a few seconds even when .


For the case and , we run the following experiment 100 times. We consider the spaces and , as well as the cost function . To determine the marginal capacity , we simulate independent random variates from a uniform distribution on , and we let be their order statistics (so that , and is the smallest observation). Then set and , and , for . The capacity (measure) of any other subset of is determined by additivity. An analogous method is used to simulate the marginal capacity on . For each pair of simulated capacities generated in this fashion, we calculate the minima for both the optimal transport problem for measures and the one for capacities, and we compare the resulting optimal values.
The horizontal coordinates of the blue dots in Figure 1(a) represent the optimal values of the optimal transport problem for capacities; the vertical coordinates of the blue dots represent the minimum values of the classical optimal transport problem.
We observe a trend that the greater the distance between the two marginal distributions, the larger the ratio between OT minimum for measures over the OT minimum for capacities. This trend is better revealed by the log-log plot in Figure 1(b), showing that the one optimal value appears to behave roughly like a power of the other. The difference between these two minima implies that the classical optimal transport minimum over probability measures is inaccurate in approximating the optimal transport minimum for capacities.
6.2. An Application in Counterparty Credit Risk
We consider a basic model in counterparty credit risk, similar to the one used in Ghossoub \BOthers. (\APACyear2023). Consider a bank that trades with two counterparties whose credit exposures and the credit ratings at the end of the year determine the counterparty credit risk losses of the bank over the next year. For simplicity, we assume that there are four credit ratings, A, B, C, and D (default), with the transition probabilities in Table 1.777Table 1 is borrowed from Hardy \BBA Saunders (\APACyear2022).
Initial State | Year End State | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
A | B | C | D | |
A | 0.990 | 0.007 | 0.002 | 0.001 |
B | 0.030 | 0.950 | 0.015 | 0.005 |
C | 0.015 | 0.020 | 0.960 | 0.005 |
D | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 |
Assume that the initial credit ratings of counterparties 1 and 2 are and , respectively. Due to ambiguity, we assume the joint rating of these two counterparties at the year-end is represented by a capacity on of the form where is a concave distortion function with 888In particular, when , this capacity is the same as the additive measure ., and is the law of a joint probability distribution with a Gaussian copula. In particular, we let be a two-dimensional Gaussian random vector with mean 0 and covariance matrix
and define , , where is the marginal cumulative distribution function of . In particular, we have:
(6.1) |
where is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. is defined similarly.
The cardinality of is . The probability of each pair of credit ratings can be calculated using the bivariate Gaussian distribution. For example
where is the bivariate normal cumulative distribution function.
We assume that each counterparty exposure has a (marginal) binomial distribution. In particular, we suppose that counterparty 1 has exposure that follows binomial(, ) and counterparty 2 has exposure that follows binomial(, ). The random vector is taken to have a Gaussian copula with correlation . We denote the corresponding probability distribution on by , and we assume that the marginal capacity (i.e., there is no distortion, or for the exposure capacity ).
We take , and . Then the cardinality of is . Again, here the joint probabilities for and can be calculated using the cumulative bivariate Gaussian distribution.
Finally, we describe the loss function, which is the sum of the losses due to the credit migrations of each counterparty:
(6.2) |
where the function represents the fraction of total exposure that will be lost in the next year, given the credit rating at the year-end. In this example, we take , , , (default).
We look for the maximum risk represented by a Choquet integral of the loss function against a capacity with prescribed marginal capacities and , as described above above. That is,
(6.3) |
Note that, unlike the optimization problems in Section 6.1, one of the given marginals in (6.3) is non-additive.



Figure 2 shows how the maximum varies along with changes in (a) the power in the distortion function, (b) the correlation , or (c) the correlation in the Gaussian copula. We observe that the maximum risk is a decreasing and convex function of the distortion parameter . This accords with intuition, as the smaller the parameter , the greater uncertainty there is regarding the marginal distribution of the credit risk factors. With the other parameters fixed, the maximum Choquet risk is an increasing and concave function of the correlation in the copula defining the distribution of the exposure factors . Again, this makes financial sense given the nature of our loss function. If the exposures were negatively correlated, then an increase in the first term in the loss function in (6.2) would tend to correspond to a decrease in the second term. This diversification effect is amplified the greater the magnitude of the negative correlation. Similarly, if is large and positive, then the tail of the losses will be fatter due to the tendency for large exposures to both counterparties to occur simultaneously.
Perhaps most interesting is Figure 2(c), which considers the impact of the correlation parameter of the copula of the credit risk factors on the maximum Choquet risk, as it reveals the nature (and underlying conservatism) of the Choquet risk measure corresponding to the capacity . The most striking aspect of the plot in Figure 2(c) is that it is not monotone; there is an interior maximum of as a function of . To understand this, we consider explicitly a simplified version of the model. In particular, we take to be binomial with parameters and , to be binomial with and , and . Based on this specification, we can compute the probabilities for the joint distribution of the exposures given in Table 2.
0.09 | 0.27 | 0 | |
0 | 0.15 | 0.33 | |
0 | 0 | 0.16 |
We further simplify the model by assuming only two credit states, default and no default, with both firms starting in the no-default state, and with default probability . The probability of both counterparties defaulting together is then
(6.4) |
while the probability of at least one of the counterparties defaulting is .
Let , so that . Here is the set of for which there is some scenario for the credit factor such that . Since we can take the credit scenario to be as extreme as possible (both counterparties default), reflecting the inherent conservatism in , we see that . Simple calculations with the bivariate normal distribution with then lead to the data in Table 3.
values | ||
0 | ||
0.0494 | ||
0.35 | ||
0.8162 | ||
0.9843 | ||
1 |
Similarly, when considering , we take the worst-case exposure scenario , and find that . Recalling that , we obtain the data in Table 4.
values | ||
---|---|---|
0 | ||
1 |
A simple calculation then yields:
and it can be seen that this function has an interior maximum (as a function of on ). It is interesting to note that this behaviour depends on the parameters of our model, such as the probabilities of the most extreme exposure and credit scenarios. For example, with instead of , similar calculations give that , which is monotone increasing in .
6.3. Comparison of Maximum Expected Shortfall and Maximum Choquet Risk with Expected Shortfall Marginal Risks
In this subsection, we will compare the Choquet risk measure defined in the current paper with the Maximum Expected Shortfall () studied in Ghossoub \BOthers. (\APACyear2023).
For a given loss random variable defined on , and for prescribed marginal probability measures on and on , the maximum expected shortfall at confidence level associated with is defined as
where is the expected shortfall with respect to the probability measure . In contrast to the maximum Choquet risk measure problem studied in this paper, when determining :
-
•
The marginal probability distributions of the risk factors on and are assumed to be known with certainty (in contrast to the case of marginal capacities, which may represent ambiguity about these marginal distributions).
-
•
The joint risk measure is restricted to be the expected shortfall computed with respect to some probability measure (in contrast to the maximum Choquet risk measure problem, in which we consider all possible Choquet risk measures on that match the given marginal Choquet risk measures on and ).
Since expected shortfall is a distortion risk measure, the MES can be written as:
(6.5) |
where
is the corresponding distortion function.
Explicitly, the Choquet Maximum Expected Shortfall () can be defined as the maximum Choquet integral of the loss function against capacities with the same marginals as .
(6.6) |
Since the feasible set for the maximum Choquet risk measure problem contains the feasible set for the maximum expected shortfall problem, we have that . In Figure 3, we compare the values of and for the loss random variable in the counterparty credit risk example described in the above subsection with different and .


Throughout the experiments, we fix . Assume that the counterparty 1 has initial rating B and exposure that follows binomial(, ) and that counterparty 2 has initial rating C and exposure that follows binomial(, ). In Figure 3(a), the probability corresponds to the law of joint rating , which can be calculated using bivariate Gaussian distribution with correlation factor ; similarly, the probability corresponds to the law of counterparty exposures , which can be determined using bivariate Gaussian distributions with correlation factor varying from to . We plot both risk measures over different correlation factor . When fixing and allowing change from to , we obtain Figure 3(b).
From the figures, one can also observe that the ratio of over is between 130% to 160%. This ratio depends on the parameter and the two given distributions, and , which are eventually determined by the parameters , , , , , , and the values in Table 1.
7. Conclusion
This paper investigates the problem of bounding a Choquet risk measure of a nonlinear function of two risk factors. Specifically, we assume given (marginal) capacities on the marginal spaces, representing the ambiguous distributions of the risk factors, and we consider the problem of finding the joint capacity on the product space with these given marginals, which maximizes or minimizes the Choquet integral of a given portfolio loss function.
We treat this problem as a generalization of the optimal transport problem to the setting of nonadditive measures. We provide explicit characterizations of the optimal solutions for finite marginal spaces, and we investigate some of their properties. Furthermore, we investigate the relationship between properties of the marginal capacities and those of the optimizers (and, more generally, capacities in the feasible set). In particular, we show that the minimizing capacity is balanced if and only if both marginal capacities are balanced, and we describe its core explicitly in that case. In contrast, in all but the most trivial cases, the maximizing capacity is not balanced.
We further discuss the connections with linear programming, showing that the optimal transport problems for capacities are linear programs, and we also characterize their duals explicitly. We investigate a series of numerical examples, including a comparison with the classical optimal transport problem, and applications to counterparty credit risk.
References
- Acerbi (\APACyear2002) \APACinsertmetastarAcerbi{APACrefauthors}Acerbi, C. \APACrefYearMonthDay2002. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleSpectral Measures of Risk: A Coherent Representation of Subjective Risk Aversion Spectral measures of risk: A coherent representation of subjective risk aversion.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Banking and Finance2671505–1518. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Artzner \BOthers. (\APACyear1999) \APACinsertmetastarArtznerDelbaenEberHeath{APACrefauthors}Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J\BHBIM.\BCBL \BBA Heath, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay1999. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleCoherent Measures of Risk Coherent measures of risk.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesMathematical Finance9203–228. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Bauer (\APACyear2012) \APACinsertmetastarBauer2012{APACrefauthors}Bauer, C. \APACrefYearMonthDay2012. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleProducts of Non-Additive Measures: a Fubini-like Theorem Products of non-additive measures: a Fubini-like theorem.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesTheory and Decision73621–647. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Brigo \BOthers. (\APACyear2013) \APACinsertmetastarBrigoMoriniPallavicini{APACrefauthors}Brigo, D., Morini, M.\BCBL \BBA Pallavicini, A. \APACrefYear2013. \APACrefbtitleCounterparty Credit Risk, Collateral and Funding: With Pricing Cases For All Asset Classes Counterparty credit risk, collateral and funding: With pricing cases for all asset classes. \APACaddressPublisherHobokenWiley. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Carlier \BBA Zhang (\APACyear2020) \APACinsertmetastarcarlier2020existence{APACrefauthors}Carlier, G.\BCBT \BBA Zhang, K\BPBIS. \APACrefYearMonthDay2020. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleExistence of solutions to principal–agent problems with adverse selection under minimal assumptions Existence of solutions to principal–agent problems with adverse selection under minimal assumptions.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Mathematical Economics8864–71. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Delbaen (\APACyear2002) \APACinsertmetastarDelbaen2002{APACrefauthors}Delbaen, F. \APACrefYearMonthDay2002. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleCoherent risk measures on general probability spaces Coherent risk measures on general probability spaces.\BBCQ \BIn K. Sandmann \BBA P. Schönbucher (\BEDS), \APACrefbtitleAdvances in Finance and Stochastics. Essays in Honour of Dieter Sondermann Advances in finance and stochastics. essays in honour of dieter sondermann (\BPGS 1–37). \APACaddressPublisherSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Denneberg (\APACyear1994) \APACinsertmetastardenneberg1994non{APACrefauthors}Denneberg, D. \APACrefYear1994. \APACrefbtitleNon-additive measure and integral Non-additive measure and integral (\BVOL 27). \APACaddressPublisherSpringer Science & Business Media. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Destercke (\APACyear2013) \APACinsertmetastarDestercke{APACrefauthors}Destercke, S. \APACrefYearMonthDay2013. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleIndependence and 2-Monotonicity: Nice to Have, Hard to Keep Independence and 2-monotonicity: Nice to have, hard to keep.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesInternational Journal of Approximate Reasoning54478–490. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Dunford \BBA Schwartz (\APACyear1958) \APACinsertmetastarDunford{APACrefauthors}Dunford, N.\BCBT \BBA Schwartz, J. \APACrefYear1958. \APACrefbtitleLinear Operators, Part 1: General Theory Linear Operators, Part 1: General Theory. \APACaddressPublisherWiley-Interscience. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Dyckerhoff (\APACyear2022) \APACinsertmetastarDyckerhoff{APACrefauthors}Dyckerhoff, R. \APACrefYearMonthDay2022. \APAChowpublishedPersonal communication. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Eckstein \BOthers. (\APACyear2021) \APACinsertmetastareckstein2021robust{APACrefauthors}Eckstein, S., Guo, G., Lim, T.\BCBL \BBA Obłój, J. \APACrefYearMonthDay2021. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleRobust pricing and hedging of options on multiple assets and its numerics Robust pricing and hedging of options on multiple assets and its numerics.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesSIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics121158–188. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Föllmer \BBA Schied (\APACyear2016) \APACinsertmetastarFollmerSchied{APACrefauthors}Föllmer, H.\BCBT \BBA Schied, A. \APACrefYear2016. \APACrefbtitleStochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time Stochastic finance: An introduction in discrete time (\PrintOrdinalFourth \BEd). \APACaddressPublisherBerlinde Gruyter. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Galichon (\APACyear2016) \APACinsertmetastarGalichon{APACrefauthors}Galichon, A. \APACrefYear2016. \APACrefbtitleOptimal Transport Methods in Economics Optimal transport methods in economics. \APACaddressPublisherPrincetonPrinceton University Press. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Garcia-Cespedes \BOthers. (\APACyear2010) \APACinsertmetastarRosenSaundersAlpha{APACrefauthors}Garcia-Cespedes, J., de Juan Herrero, J., Rosen, D.\BCBL \BBA Saunders, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay2010. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleEffective Modelling of Wrong-Way Risk, CCR Capital and Alpha in Basel II Effective modelling of wrong-way risk, CCR capital and alpha in Basel II.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Risk Model Validation4171–98. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Ghirardato (\APACyear1997) \APACinsertmetastarghirardato1997independence{APACrefauthors}Ghirardato, P. \APACrefYearMonthDay1997. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn Independence for Non-Additive Measures, with a Fubini Theorem On independence for non-additive measures, with a Fubini theorem.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Economic Theory732261–291. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Ghossoub \BOthers. (\APACyear2023) \APACinsertmetastarGHS2023{APACrefauthors}Ghossoub, M., Hall, J.\BCBL \BBA Saunders, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay2023. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleMaximum Spectral Measures of Risk with Given Risk Factor Marginal Distributions Maximum Spectral Measures of Risk with Given Risk Factor Marginal Distributions.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesMathematics of Operations Research4821158–1182. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Glasserman \BBA Yang (\APACyear2018) \APACinsertmetastarGlassermanYang{APACrefauthors}Glasserman, P.\BCBT \BBA Yang, L. \APACrefYearMonthDay2018. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleBounding Wrong-Way Risk in CVA Calculation Bounding wrong-way risk in CVA calculation.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesMathematical Finance28268–305. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Grabisch (\APACyear2016) \APACinsertmetastarGrabisch{APACrefauthors}Grabisch, M. \APACrefYear2016. \APACrefbtitleSet Functions, Games, and Capacities in Decision Making Set functions, games, and capacities in decision making. \APACaddressPublisherSwitzerlandSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Gregory (\APACyear2020) \APACinsertmetastarGregory{APACrefauthors}Gregory, J. \APACrefYear2020. \APACrefbtitleThe xVA Challenge: Counterparty Risk, Funding, Collateral, Capital and Initial Margin The xva challenge: Counterparty risk, funding, collateral, capital and initial margin. \APACaddressPublisherJohn Wiley & Sons. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Guillen \BBA Kitagawa (\APACyear2017) \APACinsertmetastarguillen2017pointwise{APACrefauthors}Guillen, N.\BCBT \BBA Kitagawa, J. \APACrefYearMonthDay2017. \BBOQ\APACrefatitlePointwise estimates and regularity in geometric optics and other generated Jacobian equations Pointwise estimates and regularity in geometric optics and other generated jacobian equations.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesCommunications on Pure and Applied Mathematics7061146–1220. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Hardy \BBA Saunders (\APACyear2022) \APACinsertmetastarHardySaundersQERM{APACrefauthors}Hardy, M.\BCBT \BBA Saunders, D. \APACrefYear2022. \APACrefbtitleQuantitative Enterprise Risk Management Quantitative enterprise risk management. \APACaddressPublisherCambridge, U.K.Cambridge University Press. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Hendon \BOthers. (\APACyear1991) \APACinsertmetastarhendon1991s{APACrefauthors}Hendon, E., Jacobsen, H., Sloth, B.\BCBL \BBA Tran, T. \APACrefYearMonthDay1991. \APACrefbtitleThe product of capacities and lower probabilities The product of capacities and lower probabilities \APACbVolEdTR\BTR. \APACaddressInstitutionmimeo, University of Copenhagen. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Henry-Labordère (\APACyear2017) \APACinsertmetastarHenryLabordereMFHBook{APACrefauthors}Henry-Labordère, P. \APACrefYear2017. \APACrefbtitleModel-Free Hedging: A Martingale Optimal Transport Viewpoint Model-free hedging: A martingale optimal transport viewpoint. \APACaddressPublisherBoca RatonCRC Press. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Kantorovich (\APACyear1942) \APACinsertmetastarkantorovich1942{APACrefauthors}Kantorovich, L. \APACrefYearMonthDay1942. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn the translocation of masses On the translocation of masses.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesC.R. (Doklady) Acad. Sci. URSS (N.S.)37199–201. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Kantorovich (\APACyear1948) \APACinsertmetastarkantorovich1948{APACrefauthors}Kantorovich, L. \APACrefYearMonthDay1948. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn a problem of Monge (In Russian) On a problem of Monge (in russian).\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesUspekhi Math. Nauk.3225–226. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Korman \BBA McCann (\APACyear2015) \APACinsertmetastarkorman2015optimal{APACrefauthors}Korman, J.\BCBT \BBA McCann, R. \APACrefYearMonthDay2015. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOptimal transportation with capacity constraints Optimal transportation with capacity constraints.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesTransactions of the American Mathematical Society36731501–1521. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Korman \BOthers. (\APACyear2015) \APACinsertmetastarkorman2015dual{APACrefauthors}Korman, J., McCann, R.\BCBL \BBA Seis, C. \APACrefYearMonthDay2015. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleDual potentials for capacity constrained optimal transport Dual potentials for capacity constrained optimal transport.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesCalculus of Variations and Partial Differential Equations541573–584. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Koshevoy (\APACyear1998) \APACinsertmetastarKoshevoy{APACrefauthors}Koshevoy, G. \APACrefYearMonthDay1998. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleDistributive Lattices and Products of Capacities Distributive lattices and products of capacities.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications219427–441. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Kusuoka (\APACyear2001) \APACinsertmetastarKusuoka{APACrefauthors}Kusuoka, S. \APACrefYearMonthDay2001. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn Law Invariant Coherent Risk Measures On law invariant coherent risk measures.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesAdvances in Mathematical Economics383–95. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Marinacci \BBA Montrucchio (\APACyear2004) \APACinsertmetastarmontrucchiointroduction{APACrefauthors}Marinacci, M.\BCBT \BBA Montrucchio, L. \APACrefYearMonthDay2004. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleIntroduction to the Mathematics of Ambiguity Introduction to the mathematics of ambiguity.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesUncertainty in Economic Theory, I. Gilboa (ed.)46–107. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- R. McCann (\APACyear2020) \APACinsertmetastarmccann2018displacement{APACrefauthors}McCann, R. \APACrefYearMonthDay2020. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleDisplacement convexity of Boltzmann’s entropy characterizes the strong energy condition from general relativity Displacement convexity of boltzmann’s entropy characterizes the strong energy condition from general relativity.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesCamb. J. Math.83609-681. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- R\BPBIJ. McCann \BBA Zhang (\APACyear2019) \APACinsertmetastarmccann2019concavity{APACrefauthors}McCann, R\BPBIJ.\BCBT \BBA Zhang, K\BPBIS. \APACrefYearMonthDay2019. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn concavity of the monopolist’s problem facing consumers with nonlinear price preferences On concavity of the monopolist’s problem facing consumers with nonlinear price preferences.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesCommunications on Pure and Applied Mathematics7271386–1423. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- McNeil \BOthers. (\APACyear2015) \APACinsertmetastarMcNeilFreyEmbrechts{APACrefauthors}McNeil, A., Frey, R.\BCBL \BBA Embrechts, P. \APACrefYear2015. \APACrefbtitleQuantitative Risk Management Quantitative risk management (\PrintOrdinalSecond \BEd). \APACaddressPublisherPrincetonPrinceton University Press. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Memartoluie \BOthers. (\APACyear2017) \APACinsertmetastarMemartoluieSaundersWirjanto{APACrefauthors}Memartoluie, A., Saunders, D.\BCBL \BBA Wirjanto, T. \APACrefYearMonthDay2017. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleWrong-Way Risk Bounds in Counterparty Credit Risk Management Wrong-way risk bounds in counterparty credit risk management.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions102150–163. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Monge (\APACyear1781) \APACinsertmetastarmonge1781memoire{APACrefauthors}Monge, G. \APACrefYearMonthDay1781. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleMémoire sur la théorie des déblais et des remblais (Dissertation on the theory of cuttings and embankments) Mémoire sur la théorie des déblais et des remblais (Dissertation on the theory of cuttings and embankments).\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesMem. Math. Phys. Acad. Royale Sci.666–704. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Panaretos \BBA Zemel (\APACyear2022) \APACinsertmetastarPanaretosZemel{APACrefauthors}Panaretos, V.\BCBT \BBA Zemel, Y. \APACrefYear2022. \APACrefbtitleAn Invitation to Statistics in Wasserstein Space An invitation to statistics in Wasserstein space. \APACaddressPublisherChamSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Pennanen \BBA Perkkiö (\APACyear2019) \APACinsertmetastarPennanenPerkkio2019{APACrefauthors}Pennanen, T.\BCBT \BBA Perkkiö, A\BHBIP. \APACrefYearMonthDay2019. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleConvex Duality in Nonlinear Optimal Transport Convex duality in nonlinear optimal transport.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Functional Analysis277141029–1060. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Peyré \BBA Cuturi (\APACyear2019) \APACinsertmetastarpeyre2019computational{APACrefauthors}Peyré, G.\BCBT \BBA Cuturi, M. \APACrefYearMonthDay2019. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleComputational optimal transport: With applications to data science Computational optimal transport: With applications to data science.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesFoundations and Trends® in Machine Learning115-6355–607. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Quiggin (\APACyear1982) \APACinsertmetastarquiggin82{APACrefauthors}Quiggin, J. \APACrefYearMonthDay1982. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleA Theory of Anticipated Utility A theory of anticipated utility.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Economic Behavior & Organization34323–343. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Quiggin (\APACyear1993) \APACinsertmetastarquiggin93{APACrefauthors}Quiggin, J. \APACrefYear1993. \APACrefbtitleGeneralized Expected Utility Theory - The Rank-Dependent Model Generalized expected utility theory - the rank-dependent model. \APACaddressPublisherKluwer Academic Publishers. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Rachev \BBA Rüschendorf (\APACyear1998) \APACinsertmetastarRachevRuschendorf{APACrefauthors}Rachev, S.\BCBT \BBA Rüschendorf, L. \APACrefYear1998. \APACrefbtitleMass Transportation Problems Mass transportation problems. \APACaddressPublisherNew YorkSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Rosen \BBA Saunders (\APACyear2010) \APACinsertmetastarRosenSaundersST{APACrefauthors}Rosen, D.\BCBT \BBA Saunders, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay2010. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleComputing and Stress Testing Counterparty Credit Risk Capital Computing and stress testing counterparty credit risk capital.\BBCQ \BIn E. Canabarro (\BED), \APACrefbtitleCounterparty Credit Risk Counterparty credit risk (\BPGS 245–292). \APACaddressPublisherRiskBooks. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Rosen \BBA Saunders (\APACyear2012) \APACinsertmetastarRosenSaundersCVA{APACrefauthors}Rosen, D.\BCBT \BBA Saunders, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay2012. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleCVA the Wrong Way CVA the wrong way.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesJournal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions53252–272. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Rüschendorf (\APACyear2013) \APACinsertmetastarRuschendorfMathematicalRiskAnalysis{APACrefauthors}Rüschendorf, L. \APACrefYear2013. \APACrefbtitleMathematical Risk Analysis Mathematical risk analysis. \APACaddressPublisherBerlinSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Santambrogio (\APACyear2015) \APACinsertmetastarsantambrogio2015optimal{APACrefauthors}Santambrogio, F. \APACrefYearMonthDay2015. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOptimal Transport for Applied Mathematicians Optimal transport for applied mathematicians.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesBirkäuser, NY5558-6394. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Schmeidler (\APACyear1986) \APACinsertmetastarSchmeidler86{APACrefauthors}Schmeidler, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay1986. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleIntegral representation without additivity Integral representation without additivity.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesProceedings of the American Mathematical Society255 – 261. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Schmeidler (\APACyear1989) \APACinsertmetastarschmeidler1989subjective{APACrefauthors}Schmeidler, D. \APACrefYearMonthDay1989. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleSubjective probability and expected utility without additivity Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesEconometrica571–587. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Shapiro (\APACyear2013) \APACinsertmetastarShapiro2013{APACrefauthors}Shapiro, A. \APACrefYearMonthDay2013. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleOn Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesMathematics of Operations Research381142–152. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Torra (\APACyear2023) \APACinsertmetastarTorra{APACrefauthors}Torra, V. \APACrefYearMonthDay2023. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleThe Transport Problem for Non-Additive Measures The transport problem for non-additive measures.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesEuropean Journal of Operational Research. {APACrefDOI} \doihttps://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2023.03.016 \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Torres \BOthers. (\APACyear2021) \APACinsertmetastarTorresPereiraAmini{APACrefauthors}Torres, L., Pereira, L.\BCBL \BBA Amini, M. \APACrefYearMonthDay2021. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleA Survey on Optimal Transport for Machine Learning: Theory and Applications A survey on optimal transport for machine learning: Theory and applications.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesarXiv preprint arXiv:2106.01963. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Villani (\APACyear2003) \APACinsertmetastarVillaniTopicsInOT{APACrefauthors}Villani, C. \APACrefYear2003. \APACrefbtitleTopics in Optimal Transportation Topics in optimal transportation. \APACaddressPublisherProvidenceAmerican Mathematical Society. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Villani (\APACyear2008) \APACinsertmetastarVillaniOTOldAndNew{APACrefauthors}Villani, C. \APACrefYear2008. \APACrefbtitleOptimal Transport, Old and New Optimal transport, old and new. \APACaddressPublisherBerlinSpringer. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Walley \BBA Fine (\APACyear1982) \APACinsertmetastarWalleyFine{APACrefauthors}Walley, P.\BCBT \BBA Fine, T. \APACrefYearMonthDay1982. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleTowards a frequentist theory of upper and lower probability Towards a frequentist theory of upper and lower probability.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesAnnals of Statistics103741–761. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Yaari (\APACyear1987) \APACinsertmetastaryaari1987dual{APACrefauthors}Yaari, M. \APACrefYearMonthDay1987. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleThe dual theory of choice under risk The dual theory of choice under risk.\BBCQ \APACjournalVolNumPagesEconometrica95–115. \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib
- Zhang \BOthers. (\APACyear2020) \APACinsertmetastarzhang2020wasserstein{APACrefauthors}Zhang, K., Peyré, G., Fadili, J.\BCBL \BBA Pereyra, M. \APACrefYearMonthDay2020. \BBOQ\APACrefatitleWasserstein control of mirror langevin monte carlo Wasserstein control of mirror langevin monte carlo.\BBCQ \BIn \APACrefbtitleConference on Learning Theory Conference on learning theory (\BPGS 3814–3841). \PrintBackRefs\CurrentBib