This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

A geometric analysis of nonlinear dynamics and its application to financial time series

Isao Shoji [email protected] Tokyo University of Science, Fujimi, Chiyoda, Tokyo 102-0071, Japan Masahiro Nozawa
Abstract

A geometric method to analyze nonlinear oscillations is discussed. We consider a nonlinear oscillation modeled by a second order ordinary differential equation without specifying the function form. By transforming the differential equation into the system of first order ordinary differential equations, the trajectory is embedded in R3R^{3} as a curve, and thereby the time evolution of the original state can be translated into the behavior of the curve in R3R^{3}, or the vector field along the curve. We analyze the vector field to investigate the dynamic properties of a nonlinear oscillation. While the function form of the model is unspecified, the vector fields and those associated quantities can be estimated by a nonparametric filtering method. We apply the proposed analysis to the time series of the Japanese stock price index. The application shows that the vector field and its derivative will be used as the tools of picking up various signals that help understanding of the dynamic properties of the stock price index.

keywords:
Stochastic differential equation; Nonparametric filter; Vector field; Geodesics;

1 Introduction

Nonlinear oscillations are ubiquitous phenomena from natural science to social science. Various method of analyzing their dynamic properties have been proposed. For example, neural oscillations are modeled by nonlinear oscillations which are estimated from EEG time series (Riera et al., 2004, Stephan, et al., 2008, Valdes-Sosa et al., 2009, Havlicek et al., 2011, Livina et al., 2011), heart rate variability is modeled by nonlinear oscillations to monitor the states of the heart (Grudzinski and Zebrowski, 2004, Gois and Savi 2009, Zebrowski et al 2007), population dynamics in epidemiology are analyzed by stochastic differential equations (Gao et al, 2019, Wang et al, 2018), the light curves of active galactic nuclei in astronomy (Misra and Zdziarski, 2008, Phillipson et al., 2018), and dynamic behavior of asset prices in finance (Chiarella et al., 2009, Date and Ponomareva, 2011), and so on.

Mathematically a nonlinear oscillation can be modeled by the following second order ordinary differential equation:

x¨=f(x,x˙).\ddot{x}=f(x,\dot{x}). (1)

This differential equation is equivalent to the system of the first order ordinary differential equations:

dx1\displaystyle dx_{1} =\displaystyle= x2dt\displaystyle x_{2}dt
dx2\displaystyle dx_{2} =\displaystyle= f(x1,x2)dt\displaystyle f(x_{1},x_{2})dt

where x1=xx_{1}=x and x2=x˙x_{2}=\dot{x}. Since the dynamic behavior of the solution, or trajectory, x(t)x(t) corresponds to that of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) in R2R^{2}, the latter is more useful to analyze the dynamic behavior from a geometric point of view, and thus we focus on the trajectory of the first order differential equation instead of the original one (1). Moreover, the trajectory of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) is more informative because it contains the information on the velocity. Hence, more merit will be expected in analyzing the trajectory of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) than that of x(t)x(t).

Here, we should note that the behavior of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) is restricted by ff in (1). To express the restriction by ff more explicitly, we may embed the trajectory of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) into the 3-dimensional Euclidean space R3R^{3} by constructing a manifold MM by M={(x1,x2,x3)|x3=f(x1,x2)}M=\{(x_{1},x_{2},x_{3})|x_{3}=f(x_{1},x_{2})\}. Then, the behavior of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) is transformed into that of (x1(t),x2(t),x3(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t),x_{3}(t)) where x3(t)=f(x1(t),x2(t))x_{3}(t)=f(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)). The behavior of (x1(t),x2(t),x3(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t),x_{3}(t)) is more informative because it contains the information on the acceleration. Hence, we will enjoy such a merit as discussed in this paper, by analyzing the trajectory, or more geometrically speaking the curve (x1(t),x2(t),x3(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t),x_{3}(t)) in R3R^{3} instead of the curve (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) in R2R^{2}.

The dynamics of γ(t)=(x1(t),x2(t),x3(t))\gamma(t)=(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t),x_{3}(t)) can be characterized by the vector field V=dγ/dtV=d\gamma/dt along the curve γ(t)\gamma(t); in other words, to know VV is to know the dynamics of γ(t)\gamma(t). Moreover, the covariant derivative of VV along γ(t)\gamma(t), denote V\nabla V, also conveys useful information on the curve γ(t)\gamma(t). For example, if V=0\nabla V=0, γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic, implying that among the curves joining pp to qq (p,qM)(p,q\in M) the length of γ\gamma from p=γ(t1)p=\gamma(t_{1}) to q=γ(t2)q=\gamma(t_{2}) is the shortest. When considering the transition from pp to qq, if the covariant derivative V=0\nabla V=0, the transition by γ\gamma is the most efficient in a certain sense. Hence, by checking whether V=0\nabla V=0 from moment to moment, we can decide whether or not the transition implied by an oscillation is efficient.

The function form of ff plays a crucial role in the dynamic behavior of γ(t)\gamma(t). For real applications, however, it is quite difficult to specify the function form beforehand. Rather, the information on the function form needs to be derived from data. To this end, nonparametric methods may be useful. However, every nonparametric method is not necessarily applicable to our setting because in general we can not expect to observe all the data necessary for the analysis above; x1x_{1} could be observed but, generally speaking, neither x2x_{2} nor x3x_{3} is expected to be observed. In fact, since nonparametric modeling based on regression (Fan and Gijbels, 1998, Fan and Yao, 2005, Fan and Zhang, 2003) requires an objective variable as well as explanatory variables, the modeling does not work under the circumstances that only partially observed data is available. To this end, methods of filtering may be useful. Hence, the nonparametric filtering method discussed in Shoji (2020) is used in this paper. Even from partially observed data, the method enables us to estimate unobservable states by the method of filtering.

By applying the proposed analysis together with the nonparametric filtering method, we conduct an empirical analysis of financial time series. Using daily data of the Japanese stock price index, or Nikkei225, of sample size more than 10,000, we investigate the dynamic properties of the index price by the vector field and its covariant derivative. With estimated vector fields and their covariant derivatives we compare the transitive properties of Nikkei225 from year to year through relating those behaviors with the historical events.

The paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we explain the geometric method for analyzing the time series of the light ratio. In section 3 we develop a nonparametric method to estimate quantities used for the above analysis. An application of the proposed analysis to the financial time series are explained in section 4. We conclude in the final section.

2 Geometric analysis

As in Shoji et al (2020), we suppose that a nonlinear oscillation satisfies the following 2nd order differential equation:

x¨f(x,x˙)\displaystyle\ddot{x}-f(x,\dot{x}) =\displaystyle= 0.\displaystyle 0. (2)

This differential equation can be reformulated by,

dx1\displaystyle dx_{1} =\displaystyle= x2dt,\displaystyle x_{2}dt, (3)
dx2\displaystyle dx_{2} =\displaystyle= f(x1,x2)dt,\displaystyle f(x_{1},x_{2})dt, (4)

where x1=xx_{1}=x, x2=dx1/dtx_{2}=dx_{1}/dt.

Usually the curve of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) is analyzed in the phase space with x1x_{1} and x2x_{2} axis. However, since the dynamics of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) is affected by ff in (4), the influence of ff on the dynamics should be taken into account. Thus, we embed the curve of (x1(t),x2(t))(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t)) into the 3-dimensional Euclidean space R3R^{3} by constructing a manifold MM by M={(x1,x2,x3)R3|x3=f(x1,x2)}M=\{(x_{1},x_{2},x_{3})\in R^{3}|x_{3}=f(x_{1},x_{2})\}. Here note that three coordinates x1x_{1} to x3x_{3} in MM mean the original state, its velocity, and its acceleration. This coordinate system is well known to the so-called differential phase space and is convenient to grasp the dynamic behavior of the curve geometrically. Let γ(t)\gamma(t) be the point of MM at time tt. Given an interval IRI\subset R, for tIt\in I γ(t)\gamma(t) shows the curve on MM, more specifically it moves with satisfying the system of differential equations because x2=x˙1x_{2}=\dot{x}_{1} and x3=x˙2x_{3}=\dot{x}_{2}. γ(t)\gamma(t) is considered to be more informative than the original state x1(t)x_{1}(t) itself because γ(t)\gamma(t) additionally contains the information on velocity and acceleration. Hence, we are mainly interested in γ(t)\gamma(t). In particular, the dynamic behavior of γ(t)\gamma(t) can be characterized by the vector field along γ(t)\gamma(t), or V=dγ/dtV=d\gamma/dt, which belongs to the tangent space Tγ(t)(M)T_{\gamma(t)}(M). While VV determines the local behavior of γ(t)\gamma(t), the integral curve of VV becomes γ(t)\gamma(t) and thus we can grasp the global behavior of γ(t)\gamma(t) through VV as well.

2.1 Covariant derivative

The time change of γ(t)\gamma(t) is characterized by VV, and thus it sounds reasonable that the time change of VV can be characterized by the derivative of VV, or dV/dtdV/dt. However, this is not necessarily true because γ(t)\gamma(t) lies in MM so that the component of dV/dtdV/dt perpendicular to Tγ(t)MT_{\gamma(t)}M will have no effect on the behavior of VV. Hence, the projection of dV/dtdV/dt to Tγ(t)MT_{\gamma(t)}M is needed, which is given by the covariant derivative of VV along γ(t)\gamma(t), denoted by V\nabla V in this paper.

Since V\nabla V is a kind of derivatives of VV, V\nabla V will give useful information on the dynamics of VV. For example, if the derivative of VV is zero, it may be reasonable to consider that V\|V\| is constant. This intuition is correct if γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic. Actually, because V,V{\langle}V,V{\rangle} is scalar, V,V=ddtV,V\nabla{\langle}V,V{\rangle}={d\over dt}{\langle}V,V{\rangle}. On the other hand, because \nabla is compatible with the metric ,{\langle}\cdot,\cdot{\rangle} and the metric is symmetric, V,V=2V,V\nabla{\langle}V,V{\rangle}=2{\langle}\nabla V,V{\rangle}. Because V=0\nabla V=0 if γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic, ddtV,V=0{d\over dt}{\langle}V,V{\rangle}=0, implying V\|V\| is constant.

Moreover, if γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic joining pp to qq in MM, the length of γ(t)\gamma(t) from pp to qq is the shortest among those of curves joining pp to qq; a geodesic gives the shortest path form pp to qq. This implies that γ(t)\gamma(t) will produce an efficient behavior in a certain sense if it is a geodesic. Hence, it may be interesting to see whether γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic, which can be easily seen by checking whether V=0\nabla V=0.

V\nabla V can be expressed as the linear combination of the basis E1,E2E_{1},E_{2} of Tγ(t)MT_{\gamma(t)}M, β1E1+β2E2\beta_{1}E_{1}+\beta_{2}E_{2}, whose coefficient vector β=(β1,β2)T\beta=(\beta_{1},\beta_{2}){{}^{T}} is given by,

β\displaystyle\beta =\displaystyle= (XXT)1XdVdtT,\displaystyle(X{{}^{T}}X)^{-1}X{{}^{T}}{dV\over dt},
X\displaystyle X =\displaystyle= (1001fx1fx2).\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cc}1&0\\ 0&1\\ {\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}&{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}\end{array}\right).

with,

dV/dt\displaystyle dV/dt =\displaystyle= x˙2x1+f˙x2+f¨x3,\displaystyle\dot{x}_{2}{\partial\over\partial x_{1}}+\dot{f}{\partial\over\partial x_{2}}+\ddot{f}{\partial\over\partial x_{3}}, (7)
=\displaystyle= fx1+(fx1x2+fx2f)x2\displaystyle f{\partial\over\partial x_{1}}+({\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}x_{2}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}f){\partial\over\partial x_{2}}
+(2fx12x22+22fx1x2x2f+fx1f\displaystyle+({\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}^{2}}x_{2}^{2}+2{\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}\partial x_{2}}x_{2}f+{\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}f
+2fx22f2+fx2(fx1x2+fx2f))x3,\displaystyle+{\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{2}^{2}}f^{2}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}({\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}x_{2}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}f)){\partial\over\partial x_{3}},
E1\displaystyle E_{1} =\displaystyle= x1+fx1x3,\displaystyle{\partial\over\partial x_{1}}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}{\partial\over\partial x_{3}}, (8)
E2\displaystyle E_{2} =\displaystyle= x2+fx2x3.\displaystyle{\partial\over\partial x_{2}}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}{\partial\over\partial x_{3}}. (9)

See Shoji et al (2020) for the detail derivation.

3 Estimation method

The geometric analysis explained in the previous section can be carried out if ff is known. Actually, however, ff is unknown in almost all the real applications. Besides, we have almost no way to retrieve necessary information on its function before analysis. Furthermore, we are usually unable to access all the information on γ(t)\gamma(t); it is often the case that x1x_{1} is observable but neither x2x_{2} nor x3x_{3}. So, we assume only x1x_{1} to be observable in the following. Under these restrictions, we try to estimate necessary quantities required for the analysis.

Let X1,tX_{1,t} and X2,tX_{2,t} be stochastic processes corresponding to x1x_{1} and x2x_{2} in (3)-(4), respectively. The processes are assumed to follow the SDE below:

dX1,t\displaystyle dX_{1,t} =\displaystyle= X2,tdt+σ1dB1,t,\displaystyle X_{2,t}dt+\sigma_{1}dB_{1,t}, (10)
dX2,t\displaystyle dX_{2,t} =\displaystyle= f(X1,t,X2,t)dt+σ2dB2,t,\displaystyle f(X_{1,t},X_{2,t})dt+\sigma_{2}dB_{2,t}, (11)

where (B1,t,B2,t)(B_{1,t},B_{2,t}) is a 2-variate standard Brownian motion with constant diffusion coefficients σ1\sigma_{1} and σ2\sigma_{2}. Here, no function form of ff is assumed. In addition, only X1,tX_{1,t} is observable and it contains observation error. So, given observed time series of X1,tX_{1,t}, denote {Ztk}1kn\{Z_{t_{k}}\}_{1\leq k\leq n} (Δt=tktk1)(\Delta t=t_{k}-t_{k-1}), ZtkZ_{t_{k}} is associate with X1,tX_{1,t} by,

Ztk\displaystyle Z_{t_{k}} =\displaystyle= X1,tk+εk,\displaystyle X_{1,t_{k}}+\varepsilon_{k}, (12)

where {εk}1kn\{\varepsilon_{k}\}_{1\leq k\leq n} is assumed to be independently identically normally distributed with mean zero and variance σε2\sigma_{\varepsilon}^{2}.

Under the settings above, to estimate the SDE without specifying ff, a nonparametric method may be required. In addition, the model has to be estimated from partially observed data. To meet these requirements, we apply a nonparametric filtering (NPF) method discussed in Shoji (2020). According to the NPF method of the third order expansion, the discretized version of the state space model is given as follows. Let the state vector ξk\xi_{k} at discrete time tkt_{k} be a vector in 𝐑8{\mathbf{R}}^{8}, which is given by,

ξk=(X1,tk,X2,tk,Ytk(0,0),Ytk(1,0),Ytk(0,1),Ytk(2,0),Ytk(1,1),Ytk(0,2)),T\xi_{k}=(X_{1,t_{k}},X_{2,t_{k}},Y^{(0,0)}_{t_{k}},Y^{(1,0)}_{t_{k}},Y^{(0,1)}_{t_{k}},Y^{(2,0)}_{t_{k}},Y^{(1,1)}_{t_{k}},Y^{(0,2)}_{t_{k}}){{}^{T}}, (13)

where,

Yt(0,0)\displaystyle Y^{(0,0)}_{t} =\displaystyle= f(Xt),Yt(1,0)=fx1(Xt),Yt(0,1)=fx2(Xt),\displaystyle f(X_{t}),\ Y^{(1,0)}_{t}={\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}(X_{t}),\ Y^{(0,1)}_{t}={\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}(X_{t}),
Yt(2,0)\displaystyle Y^{(2,0)}_{t} =\displaystyle= 2fx12(Xt),Yt(1,1)=2fx1x2(Xt),Yt(0,2)=2fx22(Xt).\displaystyle{\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}^{2}}(X_{t}),\ Y^{(1,1)}_{t}={\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}\partial x_{2}}(X_{t}),\ Y^{(0,2)}_{t}={\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{2}^{2}}(X_{t}).

Because we have no assumption about the function form of ff, we also need to estimate the values of the function and its derivatives from {Ztk}1kn\{Z_{t_{k}}\}_{1\leq k\leq n}. This is why additional six states are considered as unobservable states.

The state vector ξk\xi_{k} satisfies the following system and observation equations. See appendix for the detail formula.

ξk+1\displaystyle\xi_{k+1} =\displaystyle= Fkξk+ck+ek+1,\displaystyle F_{k}\xi_{k}+c_{k}+e_{k+1}, (14)
Ytk\displaystyle Y_{t_{k}} =\displaystyle= Hξk+εtk.\displaystyle H\xi_{k}+\varepsilon_{t_{k}}. (15)

Applying the Kalman updating formula to the above state space model, the filter and prediction of ξk\xi_{k}, which are given as ξk|k=E[ξk|{Ztj}1jk]\xi_{k|k}=E[\xi_{k}|\{Z_{t_{j}}\}_{1\leq j\leq k}] and ξk+1|k=E[ξk+1|{Ztj}1jk]\xi_{k+1|k}=E[\xi_{k+1}|\{Z_{t_{j}}\}_{1\leq j\leq k}], can be computed as follows.

ξk+1|k\displaystyle\xi_{k+1|k} =\displaystyle= Fkξk|k+ck,\displaystyle F_{k}\xi_{k|k}+c_{k}, (16)
Σk+1|k\displaystyle\Sigma_{k+1|k} =\displaystyle= FkΣk|kFkT+Qk,\displaystyle F_{k}\Sigma_{k|k}F_{k}^{T}+Q_{k}, (17)
Kk\displaystyle K_{k} =\displaystyle= Σk|k1HT(HΣk|k1HT+σε2)1,\displaystyle\Sigma_{k|k-1}H^{T}(H\Sigma_{k|k-1}H^{T}+\sigma_{\varepsilon}^{2})^{-1}, (18)
ξk|k\displaystyle\xi_{k|k} =\displaystyle= ξk|k1+Kk(XtkHξk|k1),\displaystyle\xi_{k|k-1}+K_{k}(X_{t_{k}}-H\xi_{k|k-1}), (19)
Σk|k\displaystyle\Sigma_{k|k} =\displaystyle= (IKkH)Σk|k1,\displaystyle(I-K_{k}H)\Sigma_{k|k-1}, (20)

where,

Σk+1|k\displaystyle\Sigma_{k+1|k} =\displaystyle= E[(ξk+1ξk+1|k)(ξk+1ξk+1|k)T|{Ztj}1jk],\displaystyle E\left[(\xi_{k+1}-\xi_{k+1|k})(\xi_{k+1}-\xi_{k+1|k})^{T}\left|\{Z_{t_{j}}\}_{1\leq j\leq k}\right.\right],
Σk|k\displaystyle\Sigma_{k|k} =\displaystyle= E[(ξkξk|k)(ξkξk|k)T|{Ztj}1jk],\displaystyle E\left[(\xi_{k}-\xi_{k|k})(\xi_{k}-\xi_{k|k})^{T}\left|\{Z_{t_{j}}\}_{1\leq j\leq k}\right.\right],
Qk\displaystyle Q_{k} =\displaystyle= E[ek+1ek+1T|{Ztj}1jk].\displaystyle E\left[e_{k+1}e_{k+1}^{T}\left|\{Z_{t_{j}}\}_{1\leq j\leq k}\right.\right].

Then the estimates of the unobservable states of our interest can be found in the components of ξk|k\xi_{k|k} or ξk+1|k\xi_{k+1|k}. For example, the estimate of the unobservable state X2,tkX_{2,t_{k}} is given by the second component of ξk|k\xi_{k|k}, and the predicted values of X1,tk+1X_{1,t_{k+1}} and X2,tk+1X_{2,t_{k+1}} are given by the first and second components of ξk+1|k\xi_{k+1|k} and so on.

Here note that the system has several parameters to be estimated; the coefficients of deviation σ1\sigma_{1}, σ2\sigma_{2}, and σε\sigma_{\varepsilon} and the nuisance parameters θ0,θ1,θ2\theta_{0},\theta_{1},\theta_{2}, and θ3\theta_{3}, which correspond to Yt(3,0),Yt(2,1),Yt(1,2)Y^{(3,0)}_{t},Y^{(2,1)}_{t},Y^{(1,2)}_{t}, and Yt(0,3)Y^{(0,3)}_{t}. These parameters can be estimated by the quasi-maximum likelihood estimation from {Ztk}1kn\{Z_{t_{k}}\}_{1\leq k\leq n} by using the following likelihood function. For the parameter vector θ=(σ1,σ2,σε,θ0,θ1,θ2,θ3)\theta=(\sigma_{1},\sigma_{2},\sigma_{\varepsilon},\theta_{0},\theta_{1},\theta_{2},\theta_{3}),

L(θ)\displaystyle L(\theta) =\displaystyle= Πk=1n1p(Ztk+1|Ztk;θ),\displaystyle\Pi_{k=1}^{n-1}p(Z_{t_{k+1}}|Z_{t_{k}};\theta), (21)
p(Ztk+1|Ztk;θ)\displaystyle p(Z_{t_{k+1}}|Z_{t_{k}};\theta) =\displaystyle= (2π(HΣk+1|kHT+σε2))1/2\displaystyle(2\pi(H\Sigma_{k+1|k}H^{T}+\sigma_{\varepsilon}^{2}))^{-1/2}
×exp{(Ztk+1Hξk+1|k)22(HΣk+1|kHT+σε2)}.\displaystyle\times\exp\left\{-{(Z_{t_{k+1}}-H\xi_{k+1|k})^{2}\over 2(H\Sigma_{k+1|k}H^{T}+\sigma_{\varepsilon}^{2})}\right\}.

Then maximizing L(θ)L(\theta) with respect to θ\theta, the maximum likelihood estimate θ^\hat{\theta} is obtained.

3.1 Estimation of vector fields

For γ(t)=(x1(t),x2(t),x3(t))T\gamma(t)=(x_{1}(t),x_{2}(t),x_{3}(t)){{}^{T}}, V=dV/dtV=dV/dt and thus V\|V\| is given by,

V\displaystyle\|V\| =\displaystyle= x˙12+x˙22+x˙32,\displaystyle\sqrt{\dot{x}_{1}^{2}+\dot{x}_{2}^{2}+\dot{x}_{3}^{2}}, (23)
x˙1\displaystyle\dot{x}_{1} =\displaystyle= x2,\displaystyle x_{2},
x˙2\displaystyle\dot{x}_{2} =\displaystyle= f(x1,x2),\displaystyle f(x_{1},x_{2}),
x˙3\displaystyle\dot{x}_{3} =\displaystyle= fx1x˙1+fx2x˙2.\displaystyle{\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}\dot{x}_{1}+{\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}\dot{x}_{2}.

Here note that x1,x2,x3x_{1},x_{2},x_{3} are deterministic variables. Thus they need to be replaced by their estimates obtained from the NPF method. Application of the NPF method produces ξk|k\xi_{k|k}, thereby substituting the values of the variables for the components of ξk|k\xi_{k|k} as follows:

x1(tk)\displaystyle x_{1}(t_{k}) =\displaystyle= X1,tk|tk,x2(tk)=X2,tk|tk,\displaystyle X_{1,t_{k}|t_{k}},\ x_{2}(t_{k})=X_{2,t_{k}|t_{k}}, (24)
f(tk)\displaystyle f(t_{k}) =\displaystyle= Ytk|tk(0,0),\displaystyle Y^{(0,0)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}}, (25)
fx1(tk)\displaystyle{\partial f\over\partial x_{1}}(t_{k}) =\displaystyle= Ytk|tk(1,0),fx2(tk)=Ytk|tk(0,1),\displaystyle Y^{(1,0)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}},\ {\partial f\over\partial x_{2}}(t_{k})=Y^{(0,1)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}}, (26)
2fx12(tk)\displaystyle{\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}^{2}}(t_{k}) =\displaystyle= Ytk|tk(2,0),2fx1x2(tk)=Ytk|tk(1,1),\displaystyle Y^{(2,0)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}},\ {\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{1}\partial x_{2}}(t_{k})=Y^{(1,1)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}}, (27)
2fx22(tk)\displaystyle{\partial^{2}f\over\partial x_{2}^{2}}(t_{k}) =\displaystyle= Ytk|tk(0,2).\displaystyle Y^{(0,2)}_{t_{k}|t_{k}}. (28)

Plugging these estimates in the formula of V\|V\|, we get the estimate of V\|V\| at time tkt_{k}. As for the covariant derivative, because V=β1E1+β2E2\nabla V=\beta_{1}E_{1}+\beta_{2}E_{2} by using E1E_{1} and E2E_{2} in (8) and (9), the estimates of V\nabla V and its length are obtained in the same way as above.

4 Application to financial time series

We apply the proposed analysis to time series of the Japanese stock price index, called Nikkei225, sampled from 1965 to 2019 on daily basis, whose sample size is more than 10,000 in total. In the following empirical analysis we use the time series transformed into the logarithm of relative price to the initial one. We have interest in what information VV and V\nabla V convey on the dynamic behavior of the stock price index.

From a geometric viewpoint, the larger V\|V\| implies the speed of the transition of γ(t)\gamma(t) is faster; drastic behaviors of the stock price index may be seen while γ(t)\gamma(t) itself is not the stock price index but a curve in R3R^{3}. On the other hand, if V=0\nabla V=0, or equivalently V=0\|\nabla V\|=0, γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic, implying that γ(t)\gamma(t) produces the shortest path among curves joining pp to qq in the manifold MM. Thus, the transition of γ(t)\gamma(t) is thought to be efficient in a certain sense if γ(t)\gamma(t) is a geodesic; otherwise the path from pp to qq becomes a detour and the transition is thought to be inefficient.

Taking this geometric interpretation into account, we consider the dynamic behavior of Nikkei225 through those of V\|V\| and V\|\nabla V\|. In the first place, we estimate the parameters of the state space model by applying the nonparametric filtering method of 3rd order expansion to the time series and the result is presented in table 1. Then, using the estimates, we compute the length of V(tk)V(t_{k}) and V(tk)\nabla V(t_{k}) at time tkt_{k}, whose time series plots from 1967 to 2019 are displayed in figure LABEL:fig1 to LABEL:fig9. Here, the first two years are omitted to remove the influence of the initial estimates in the Kalman filtering. For each figure, the leftmost panel displays the time series plots of the logarithm of the relative price, the center panel for those of V\|V\|, and the rightmost panel for those of V\|\nabla V\|.

As indicated in the previous section, V=0\nabla V=0 implies V\|V\| is constant. Hence, expectedly small V\|\nabla V\| implies V\|V\| has small change. Actually, looking at the panel of 1991, V\|V\| moves around 0.5 from 25d to 100d, where V\|\nabla V\| shows small values. Because, when =0\nabla=0, γ(t)\gamma(t) becomes a geodesic, the transition of the index price is considered to be efficient in a certain sense.

Although we try to see the behaviors of V\|V\| and V\|\nabla V\| in more detail, their time series plots show considerably various patterns from year to year. Hence, we conduct an analysis of variance (ANOVA) for the times series of V\|V\| and V\|\nabla V\|. Looking at the group of the highest value of V\|V\|, or grouping the years in which the sample mean of V\|V\| is not significantly different from the highest, it consists of the years {\{2001,2008}\} and the second highest are and {\{1972,1987,1989,1992,2013}\}, respectively. Recalling that VV stands for the velocity of γ(t)\gamma(t), it is expected that steep upward or downward sloping of the index price may occur in the years of the group. In fact, looking at the time series plots, we had such price changes. Besides, it might be interesting to see that 2008 belongs to the group, which is related to the year of the Lehman’s collapse. On the other hand, focusing on the group of the lowest V\|V\|, it consists of {\{1994,2019}\}. According to their time series plots, so steep upward or downward sloping in the price index is not observed.

Turning our attention to the result of ANOVA for V\|\nabla V\|, the group of the highest V\|\nabla V\| consists of {\{2001,2008}\} and the groups of the second and third highest consist of {\{1972,2013}\} and {\{1974,1987,1992,2002,2009}\}, respectively. Because γ(t)\gamma(t) is thought to be far away from a geodesic, the behaviors of the index price in the years of these groups are considered to be inefficient. Interestingly, 2008 also belongs to these groups, implying the transition of the index price may be inefficient through the Lehman’s collapse.

The mean of each times series can be analyzed by ANOVA, but it may be useful for investigating the time series properties in more detail to consider the simultaneous relation between the distribution of V\|V\| and that of V\|\nabla V\|. To this end, for each year their distributions are simply explained by their sample means and standard deviations, and thereby the statistical property of each time series is characterized by the four factors; the two means and the two standard deviations. To analyze more than 50 set of time series, the principal component analysis is applied. The result is displayed in figure LABEL:fig:prin, where the horizontal axis stands for the first component and the vertical axis for the second component. The statistics tells us that the variation of more than 90 % can be explained by the first and second components. According to the Hotelling’s t2t^{2} statistic with 4 degree of freedom, each member of {\{1972(12.05),1989(10.23),1990(11.91),2008(17.15),2009(18.90)}\} is significant at the 5% significant level (9.49), whose statistics are shown in parenthesis, suggesting that the time series of these years are quite different from the others. The unique feature of the crash observed in 2008 is reported by Beccar-Varela et al. (2017) in which the difference between the crashes in 2008 and 2010 are analyzed via the wavelet methodology. Our analysis also shows that t2t^{2} statistic of 2010 (1.45) is quite different from that of 2008 (17.15).

On the other hand, from an economical viewpoint, the Japanese economy had high gross domestic products in 1972. It attained the peak of the bubble economy in 1989 and subsequently had a hard crash. The sever crash was also experienced in 2008 caused by the Lehman’s collapse. The significance of the statistics above suggests that these evidents are critical for the Japanese stock market.

5 Conclusion

We discussed a geometric analysis of nonlinear dynamics and its application to financial time series. Nonlinear dynamics considered here are modeled by the second order ordinary differential equation. Since it is useful to geometrically analyze a curve, or a solution to the differential equation, in the differential phase space, the techniques in differential geometry is applied for the analysis of the dynamic behavior of the curve; the vector field on a manifold implied by the differential equation in the differential phase space and its covariant derivative. We could derive information on the infinitesimal transition of the curve from the vector field, in other words the variability of the curve, and at the same time on the infinitesimal transition of the vector field, or the variability of the vector field, from the covariant derivative.

The analysis would work if the function form of the differential equation is specified beforehand. In real applications, however, we have almost no information on the specification especially in the case of more complex dynamics and thus the nonparametric method of filtering is used for estimation.

We apply the above analysis to daily time series of the Japanese stock price index, called Nikkei225, sampled for more than fifty years in order to analyze the dynamic behavior of the index price from one year to another. Using the nonparametric estimation method, we estimate the vector fields and their covariant derivatives from the time series. To compare the mean values of the vector fields and their covariant derivatives, the analysis of variance is applied, which revealed that the vector fields and the covariant derivatives catch different signals from the time series, but the two indicate that the drastic behavior occur from 2008 to 2009, corresponding to the years supposedly affected by the Lehman’s collapse. We also conducted a principal component analysis to see the relation between the vector fields and the covariant derivative. As expected, the result implied that the covariant derivative can be used as the variability of the vector field.

6 Appendix

This appendix provides the detail formula of the nonparametric filtering. ξk\xi_{k} satisfies the following system and observation equations. The derivation can be seen in Shoji (2020) for example.

ξk+1\displaystyle\xi_{k+1} =\displaystyle= Fkξk+ck+ek+1,\displaystyle F_{k}\xi_{k}+c_{k}+e_{k+1}, (29)
Ytk\displaystyle Y_{t_{k}} =\displaystyle= Hξk+εtk.\displaystyle H\xi_{k}+\varepsilon_{t_{k}}. (30)

where,

Fk\displaystyle F_{k} =\displaystyle= I8+GkAk,\displaystyle I_{8}+G_{k}A_{k},
ck\displaystyle c_{k} =\displaystyle= Gkbk,\displaystyle G_{k}b_{k},
ek+1\displaystyle e_{k+1} =\displaystyle= Gkϵk+1,\displaystyle G_{k}\epsilon_{k+1},

with the m×mm\times m identity matrix ImI_{m} and,

Ak\displaystyle A_{k} =\displaystyle= (0A1,2A1,3000A2,2A2,3000000),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cccccc}0&A_{1,2}&A_{1,3}&0&\cdots&0\\ 0&A_{2,2}&A_{2,3}&0&\cdots&0\\ 0&&\cdots&&&0\\ \vdots&&&&&\vdots\\ 0&&\cdots&&&0\end{array}\right),
(A1,2A1,3A2,2A2,3)\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cc}A_{1,2}&A_{1,3}\\ A_{2,2}&A_{2,3}\\ \end{array}\right) =\displaystyle= (Jtk)1{exp(JtkΔt)I2},\displaystyle(J_{t_{k}})^{-1}\left\{\exp(J_{t_{k}}\Delta t)-I_{2}\right\},
Jtk\displaystyle J_{t_{k}} =\displaystyle= (01Ytk|tk(1,0)Ytk|tk(0,1)),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cc}0&1\\ Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(1,0)}&Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(0,1)}\end{array}\right),
Gk\displaystyle G_{k} =\displaystyle= (10000100Ytk|tk(1,0)Ytk|tk(0,1)10θ1θ200θ2θ301),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cccccc}1&0&0&\cdots&&0\\ 0&1&0&\cdots&&0\\ Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(1,0)}&Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(0,1)}&1&\cdots&&0\\ \vdots&\vdots&\vdots&\ddots&&\vdots\\ \theta_{1}&\theta_{2}&0&&\ddots&0\\ \theta_{2}&\theta_{3}&0&&\cdots&1\end{array}\right),
bk\displaystyle b_{k} =\displaystyle= ((Jtk1)2{exp(JtkΔt)I2JtkΔt}Mtk(σ122Ytk|tk(2,0)+σ222Ytk|tk(0,2))Δt0),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{c}(J_{t_{k}}^{-1})^{2}\left\{\exp(J_{t_{k}}\Delta t)-I_{2}-J_{t_{k}}\Delta t\right\}M_{t_{k}}\\ ({\sigma_{1}^{2}\over 2}Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(2,0)}+{\sigma_{2}^{2}\over 2}Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(0,2)})\Delta t\\ \vdots\\ 0\\ \end{array}\right),
ek+1\displaystyle e_{k+1} =\displaystyle= (tktk+1exp{Jtk(tk+1u)}S𝑑Bu00),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{c}\int_{t_{k}}^{t_{k+1}}\exp\{J_{t_{k}}(t_{k+1}-u)\}SdB_{u}\\ 0\\ \vdots\\ 0\\ \end{array}\right),
Mtk\displaystyle M_{t_{k}} =\displaystyle= (0σ122Ytk|tk(2,0)+σ222Ytk|tk(0,2)),S=(σ1σ2),\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{c}0\\ {\sigma_{1}^{2}\over 2}Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(2,0)}+{\sigma_{2}^{2}\over 2}Y_{t_{k}|t_{k}}^{(0,2)}\end{array}\right),\ S=\left(\begin{array}[]{c}\sigma_{1}\\ \sigma_{2}\\ \end{array}\right),
H\displaystyle H =\displaystyle= (100).\displaystyle\left(\begin{array}[]{cccc}1&0&\cdots&0\\ \end{array}\right).

References

  • [1] Anderson B. D.O., Moor J. B.: Optimal Filtering. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey (1979)
  • [2] Beccar-Varela, M. P. et al.: Analysis of the Lehman Brothers collapse and the Flash Crash event by applying wavelets methodologies. Physica A 474, 162-171 (2017)
  • [3] Chiarella, C., Hung, H, To, T. D.: The volatility structure of the fixed income market under the HJM framework: A nonlinear filtering approach. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis 53, (2009)
  • [4] Date, P., Ponomareva, K.: Linear and non-linear filtering in mathematical finance: a review. IMA Journal of Management Mathematics 22, 195- 211 (2011)
  • [5] Fan, J., Gijbels, I.: Local Polynomial Modeling and Its Applications. Chapman and Hall, London. (1996)
  • [6] Fan, J., Yao, Q. W.: Nonlinear Time Series: Nonparametric and Parametric Methods. Springer. (2005)
  • [7] Fan, J., Zhang, C.: A reexamination of diffusion estimators with applications to financial model validation. Journal of the American Statistical Association 98, 118-134 (2003)
  • [8] Grudzinski, K. and Zebrowski, J. J.: Modeling cardiac pacemakers with relaxation oscillators. Physica A 336, 153-162 (2004)
  • [9] Gao, N. et al.: Dynamics of a stochastic SIS epidemic model with nonlinear incidence rates Advances in Difference Equations 2019:41, (2019)
  • [10] Gois, S.F.S.M. and Savi, M. A.: An analysis of heart rhythm dynamics using a three-coupled oscillator model. Chaos, Solitons and Fractals 41, 2553-2565 (2009)
  • [11] Havlicek, M., Friston, K.J., et al.: Dynamic modeling of neuronal responses in fMRI using cubature Kalman filtering. Neuroimage 56, 2109-2128 (2011)
  • [12] Jazwinski A.H.: Stochastic Processes and Filtering Theory. Academic Press, New York (1970)
  • [13] Jimenez, J.C., Shoji, I., Ozaki, T.: Simulation of stochastic differential equations through the local linearization method. A comparative study. Journal of Statistical Physics 94, 587-602 (1999)
  • [14] Misra, R., Zdziarski, A.A.; Damped harmonic oscillator interpretation of the soft-state power spectra of Cyg X-1. MNRAS. 387, 915?920 (2008)
  • [15] Ozaki, T.: Time series modeling of neuroscience data. CRC Press (2012)
  • [16] Phillipson R. A., Boyd P. T., Smale A.P.: The chaotic long-term X-ray variability of 4U 1705-44. MNRAS. 477, 5220-5237 (2018)
  • [17] Riera, J.J., Watanabe, J. et al.: A state-space model of the hemodynamic approach: nonlinear filtering of BOLD signals. NeuroImage 21, 547-567 (2004)
  • [18] Shoji, I.: A comparative study of maximum likelihood estimators for nonlinear dynamical system models. International Journal of Control 71, 391-404 (1998)
  • [19] Shoji, I.: A nonparametric method of estimating nonlinear dynamical system models. Physics Letters A 277, 159-168 (2000)
  • [20] Shoji, I.: Nonparametric filtering for stochastic nonlinear oscillations, forthcoming in Physical Review E (2020)
  • [21] Shoji, I., Takata, T., and Mizumoto, Y. A geometric method of analysis for the light curves of active galactic nuclei, Monthly Notices of the Royal Astronomical Society, 495, 338-349 (2020).
  • [22] Stephan, K.E., Kasper, L., et al.: Nonlinear dynamic causal models for fMRI. Neuroimage 42, 649-662 (2008)
  • [23] Valdes-Sosa, P.A., Sanchez-Bornot, J.M., et al.: Model driven EEG/fMRI fusion of brain oscillations. Human Brain Mapping 30, 2701-2721 (2009)
  • [24] Wang, W., et al.: A stochastic differential equation SIS epidemic model incorporating Ornstein?Uhlenbeck process. Physica A 509, 921-936 (2018)
  • [25] Zebrowski, J. J., et al.: Nonlinear oscillator model reproducing various phenomena in the dynamics of the conduction system of the heart. Chaos 17, 015121-11 (2007)
  • [26] Che, Y, Liu, B., et al.: Robust stabilization control of bifurcations in Hodgkin-Huxley model with aid of unscented Kalman filter. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals 101, 92-99 (2017)
  • [27] Mariani, S., Ghisi, A.: Unscented Kalman filtering for nonlinear structural dynamics. Nonlinear Dynamics 49, 131-150 (2007)
  • [28] Quach, M., Brunel, N., d’Alche-Buc, F.: Estimating parameters and hidden variables in non-linear state-space models based on ODEs for biological networks inference. Bioinformatics 23, 3209-3216 (2007)
  • [29] Sitz, A., Schwarz, U., et al.: Estimation of parameters and unobserved components for nonlinear systems from noisy time series. Physical Review E 66, 016210 (2002)
  • [30] Chen, Z.; Bayesian Filtering: From Kalman Filters to Particle Filters, and Beyond. Statistics 182, 1-69 (2003)
Table 1: Parameter estimates of the state space model: the parameters are estimated from daily time series from 1965 to 2020.
σ1\sigma_{1} σ2\sigma_{2} σε\sigma_{\varepsilon} θ0\theta_{0} θ1\theta_{1} θ2\theta_{2} θ3\theta_{3}
0.202696 0.083083 0.001351 0.022526 0.012242 0.002956 0.000934

Table 2: Summary statistics: columns of pp, V\|V\|, and V\|\nabla V\| stand for their sample means and standard deviations in parenthesis.
Year NN p=log(P/P0){p=\log(P/P_{0})} V{\|V\|} V{\|\nabla V\|} ρp,V\rho_{p,\|V\|} ρp,V\rho_{p,\|\nabla V\|} ρV,V\rho_{\|V\|,\|\nabla V\|}
1967 237 0.11394 0.15603 0.19885 0.79246 -0.76849 -0.28617
(0.05282) (0.03462) (0.04894)
1968 234 0.20401 0.13017 0.09497 0.93051 0.14746 0.46238
(0.10449) (0.04051) (0.06230)
1969 230 0.44161 0.16810 0.07584 0.78851 0.62869 0.89490
(0.07174) (0.02060) (0.04384)
1970 238 0.55242 0.16726 0.17174 0.81608 -0.65072 -0.16811
(0.07241) (0.03025) (0.05996)
1971 229 0.64372 0.15215 0.10907 0.77822 -0.08629 0.24937
(0.07090) (0.02065) (0.06177)
1972 238 1.08309 0.25833 0.27824 0.95428 0.87077 0.97758
(0.17850) (0.03767) (0.05803)
1973 233 1.32721 0.20420 0.14913 0.62832 -0.08809 0.65667
(0.06350) (0.04337) (0.10775)
1974 233 1.22120 0.18349 0.23734 -0.86304 -0.96110 0.94109
(0.08899) (0.03575) (0.13871)
1975 230 1.21959 0.14439 0.11605 -0.73858 -0.96215 0.75300
(0.04944) (0.01524) (0.09246)
1976 232 1.30884 0.13046 0.05042 0.01241 -0.45551 -0.37119
(0.02415) (0.00468) (0.03967)
1977 232 1.38560 0.12527 0.05803 -0.30551 -0.77135 0.16542
(0.02370) (0.00614) (0.05257)
1978 237 1.48319 0.12163 0.03382 0.62994 -0.24984 0.18655
(0.05094) (0.00567) (0.02298)
1979 238 1.60694 0.11488 0.02531 -0.30958 -0.18174 0.21529
(0.02597) (0.00633) (0.01635)
1980 239 1.69731 0.10669 0.02629 -0.16300 -0.47961 -0.27794
(0.02589) (0.00476) (0.01567)
1981 240 1.78806 0.10333 0.04311 0.33302 -0.10153 0.15160
(0.03344) (0.00773) (0.03131)
1982 234 1.76935 0.10525 0.10958 -0.63420 -0.92411 0.82596
(0.04251) (0.01139) (0.06062)
1983 236 1.94511 0.11324 0.07521 0.55910 0.70720 0.97579
(0.06043) (0.01102) (0.03005)
1984 243 2.12752 0.11085 0.08725 0.32730 0.37692 0.98446
(0.04605) (0.02767) (0.05379)
1985 236 2.30233 0.10388 0.09242 -0.43608 -0.38511 0.99733
(0.02639) (0.02717) (0.04666)
1986 240 2.56674 0.16419 0.19805 0.62706 0.68673 0.99472
(0.11533) (0.05883) (0.08892)
1987 238 2.91420 0.19924 0.25508 0.35484 0.36332 0.99961
(0.09050) (0.08360) (0.10496)
1988 237 3.06892 0.14109 0.18588 0.62382 0.62999 0.99984
(0.06763) (0.03660) (0.04599)
1989 239 3.29927 0.18587 0.23745 0.18610 0.10810 0.99674
(0.05444) (0.01935) (0.02354)
1990 235 3.13780 0.17219 0.17335 -0.74869 -0.64851 0.97746
(0.16557) (0.08576) (0.11722)
1991 235 2.95889 0.10122 0.09959 -0.76625 -0.83886 0.99131
(0.06223) (0.05429) (0.07596)
1992 236 2.65733 0.20611 0.28397 -0.55113 -0.62896 0.99516
(0.10379) (0.09120) (0.13054)
1993 234 2.71791 0.08241 0.10836 -0.45433 -0.56247 0.98887
(0.08164) (0.03830) (0.05935)
1994 236 2.76409 0.04059 0.04949 0.49599 0.38832 0.98249
(0.03508) (0.02214) (0.02975)
1995 241 2.61894 0.10679 0.14648 -0.77843 -0.79592 0.99564
(0.07858) (0.07076) (0.11311)
1996 236 2.81897 0.08597 0.10841 0.52135 0.53019 0.99930
(0.03476) (0.04921) (0.06302)
1997 234 2.67966 0.09648 0.13592 -0.94590 -0.95634 0.99916
(0.08169) (0.06227) (0.09371)
1998 236 2.49937 0.13432 0.20371 -0.80466 -0.82230 0.99929
(0.07523) (0.05554) (0.08597)
1999 232 2.59104 0.09451 0.11055 -0.12144 -0.32972 0.95776
(0.09204) (0.02909) (0.05429)
2000 238 2.60442 0.11250 0.15884 -0.35775 -0.53800 0.97795
(0.11250) (0.04828) (0.07466)
2001 235 2.25475 0.22490 0.35998 -0.76244 -0.79816 0.99810
(0.11762) (0.07296) (0.12222)
2002 235 2.07913 0.17321 0.27802 -0.91618 -0.92610 0.99588
(0.10896) (0.07273) (0.14253)
2003 232 1.99581 0.14762 0.19384 -0.70269 -0.79458 0.98231
(0.11066) (0.05674) (0.14507)
2004 234 2.18481 0.09315 0.07110 0.65998 0.57862 0.92957
(0.03444) (0.03006) (0.05254)
2005 232 2.28474 0.10774 0.09896 0.97701 0.93551 0.98000
(0.10598) (0.05761) (0.09767)
2006 239 2.54942 0.12557 0.15200 0.60467 0.62754 0.99847
(0.04355) (0.07000) (0.10034)
2007 244 2.60200 0.07522 0.09735 0.11316 -0.08257 0.97474
(0.05391) (0.03247) (0.04664)
2008 242 2.24833 0.24285 0.39196 -0.95172 -0.96043 0.99918
(0.19384) (0.15961) (0.27381)
2009 240 1.99972 0.17031 0.25348 -0.94603 -0.96866 0.99483
(0.10887) (0.14685) (0.28070)
2010 243 2.07242 0.09155 0.10721 -0.58194 -0.75814 0.93580
(0.06164) (0.02570) (0.07378)
2011 245 2.01027 0.10867 0.15349 -0.89222 -0.94808 0.96974
(0.07808) (0.03665) (0.09196)
2012 248 1.97875 0.09179 0.10652 -0.30963 -0.66663 0.88481
(0.05352) (0.02108) (0.06260)
2013 245 2.37491 0.20546 0.27258 0.23766 0.27363 0.99886
(0.10935) (0.05528) (0.08079)
2014 244 2.50734 0.09156 0.11397 0.82050 0.83752 0.99814
(0.06346) (0.04354) (0.06489)
2015 244 2.72446 0.12222 0.16575 0.53827 0.55264 0.99936
(0.05637) (0.06530) (0.08873)
2016 245 2.59804 0.06888 0.09501 -0.20951 -0.23297 0.99905
(0.05373) (0.04408) (0.06191)
2017 243 2.77571 0.09781 0.13567 0.88269 0.88282 0.99988
(0.06262) (0.03926) (0.05229)
2018 235 2.87413 0.08050 0.10664 0.69871 0.73871 0.98092
(0.03741) (0.03765) (0.05624)
2019 240 2.84790 0.05391 0.05684 0.74391 0.85238 0.96355
(0.04462) (0.02534) (0.04565)
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]
[Uncaptioned image]